正在加载图片...
and to satisfy prudence requirements before implementation. If profitable implementation requires regulatory and business practice changes or the creation of either new markets or new channels of intermediation, then the delay between announcement of an anomaly and its elimination by corrective action in the market place can, indeed, be a long one. Much the same story applies in varying degrees to the adoption in practice of new structural models of evaluation (e. g, option pricing models)and to the diffusion of innovations in financial products (cf. Rogers, 1972 for a general discussion of the diffusion of innovations). Recognition of the different speeds of information diffusion is particularly important in empirical research where the growth in sophisticated and sensitive technique s to test evermore-refined financial-behavioral patterns severely strains the simple information structure of our asset pricing models. To avoid inadvertent positing of a Connecticut Yankee in King Arthur's Court, empirical studies that use long historical time series to test financial- market hypotheses should take care to account for the evolution of institutions and information technologies during the sample period. It is, for example, common in tests of the weak form of the Efficient Market Hypothesis to assume that real-world investors at the time of their portfolio decisions had access to the complete prior history of all stock returns When, however, investors'decisions were made, the price data may not have been in reasonably-accessible form and the computational technology necessary to analyze all these data may not even have been invented. In such cases, the classification of all prior price data as part of the publicly-available information set may introduce an important bias against the null hypothesis All of this is not to say that the perfect-market model has not been andIII -6- and to satisfy prudence requirements before implementation. If profitable implementation requires regulatory and business practice changes or the creation of either new markets or new channels of intermediation, then the delay between announcement of an anomaly and its elimination by corrective action in the market place can, indeed, be a long one. Much the same story applies in varying degrees to the adoption in practice of new structural models of evaluation (e.g., option pricing models) and to the diffusion of innovations in financial products (cf. Rogers, 1972 for a general discussion of the diffusion of innovations). Recognition of the different speeds of information diffusion is particularly important in empirical research where the growth in sophisticated and sensitive techniques to test evermore-refined financial-behavioral patterns severely strains the simple information structure of our asset pricing models. To avoid inadvertent positing of a "Connecticut Yankee in King Arthur's Court," empirical studies that use long historical time series to test financial￾market hypotheses should take care to account for the evolution of institutions and information technologies during the sample period. It is, for example, common in tests of the weak form of the Efficient Market Hypothesis to assume that real-world investors at the time of their portfolio decisions had access to the complete prior history of all stock returns. When, however, investors' decisions were made, the price data may not have been in reasonably-accessible form and the computational technology necessary to analyze all these data may not even have been invented. In such cases, the classification of all prior price data as part of the publicly-available information set may introduce an important bias against the null hypothesis. All of this is not to say that the perfect-market model has not been and
<<向上翻页向下翻页>>
©2008-现在 cucdc.com 高等教育资讯网 版权所有