当前位置:高等教育资讯网  >  中国高校课件下载中心  >  大学文库  >  浏览文档

《宏观经济学》课程教学资源(英文版)Lecture 3-7 Economic Growth I

资源类别:文库,文档格式:PDF,文档页数:29,文件大小:436.6KB,团购合买
The question of growth is nothing new but new disguise for an age-old issue, one which has always intrigued and preoccupied economics: the present versus the future. -James Tobin If you have ever spoken with your grandparents about what their lives were like when they were young, most likely you learned an important lesson over about economics: material standards of have improved substantially over form time for most families in most countries.
点击下载完整版文档(PDF)

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_cho7: Pg 178: 25956#/eps at 100smml ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 178:25956#/eps at 100% *25956* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e ort Growth Theory The Economy in the Very Long Run User JoEkA: Job EFFo1423: 6264_-ch07: Pg 179: 26796#/eps at 1004 Wea,Feb13,20029:48

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 179:26796#/eps at 100% *26796* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM part III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e CHAPTER SEVEN Economic growth The question of growth is nothing new but a new disguise for an age-old issue, one which has alwvays intrigued and preoccupied economics: the present versus the future James Tobin If you have ever spoken with your grandparents about what their lives were like when they were young, most likely you learned an important lesson about economics: material standards of living have improved substantially over time for most families in most countries. This advance comes from rising in- comes, which have allowed people to consume greater quantities of goods and service To measure economic growth, economists use data on gross domestic prod uct, which measures the total income of everyone in the economy. The real gdP of the United States today is more than three times its 1950 level, and re gDP per person is more than twice its 1950 level. In any given year, we can also observe large differences in the standard of living among countries. Table 7-1 shows income per person in 1999 of the world's 12 most populous countries The United States tops the list with an income of $31, 910 per person. Nigeria has an income per person of only $770--less than 3 percent of the figure for the United States Our goal in this part of the book is to understand what causes these differ- ences in income over time and across countries. In Chapter 3 we identified the factors of production--capital and labor-and the production technology as the sources of the economy s output and, thus, of its total income Differences inin- come, then, must come from differences in capital, labor, and technology. Our primary task is to develop a theory of economic growth called the olow growth model. Our analysis in Chapter 3 enabled us to describe how economy produces and uses its output at one point in time. The analysis was static--a snapshot of the economy. To explain why our national income grows, and why some economies grow faster than others, we must broaden our analysis so that it describes changes in the economy over time. By developing such a model, we make our analysis dynamic--more like a movie than a phe tograph. The Solow growth model shows how saving, population growth, and User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_ ch07: Pg 180: 26797#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 180:26797#/eps at 100% *26797* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM 7 If you have ever spoken with your grandparents about what their lives were like when they were young, most likely you learned an important lesson about economics: material standards of living have improved substantially over time for most families in most countries.This advance comes from rising in￾comes, which have allowed people to consume greater quantities of goods and services. To measure economic growth, economists use data on gross domestic prod￾uct, which measures the total income of everyone in the economy. The real GDP of the United States today is more than three times its 1950 level, and real GDP per person is more than twice its 1950 level. In any given year, we can also observe large differences in the standard of living among countries. Table 7-1 shows income per person in 1999 of the world’s 12 most populous countries. The United States tops the list with an income of $31,910 per person. Nigeria has an income per person of only $770—less than 3 percent of the figure for the United States. Our goal in this part of the book is to understand what causes these differ￾ences in income over time and across countries. In Chapter 3 we identified the factors of production—capital and labor—and the production technology as the sources of the economy’s output and, thus, of its total income. Differences in in￾come, then, must come from differences in capital, labor, and technology. Our primary task is to develop a theory of economic growth called the Solow growth model. Our analysis in Chapter 3 enabled us to describe how the economy produces and uses its output at one point in time. The analysis was static—a snapshot of the economy. To explain why our national income grows, and why some economies grow faster than others, we must broaden our analysis so that it describes changes in the economy over time. By developing such a model, we make our analysis dynamic—more like a movie than a pho￾tograph.The Solow growth model shows how saving, population growth, and CHAPTER The question of growth is nothing new but a new disguise for an age-old issue, one which has always intrigued and preoccupied economics: the present versus the future. — James Tobin 180 | SEVEN Economic Growth I

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I 181 table 7-1 International Differences in the Standard of Living: 1999 Income per Person Income per Person United States s31,910 China 3,550 Indonesia 23.510 India 2.230 8,070 Pakistan Bangladesh Brazil 70 Source: World bank echnological progress affect the level of an economy's output and its growth over time. In this chapter we analyze the roles of saving and population rowth. In the next chapter we introduce technological progress 7-1 The Accumulation of Capital The Solow growth model is designed to show how growth in the capital stock, growth in the labor force, and advances in technology interact in an economy, d how they affect a nations total output of goods and services. We build this nodel in steps. Our first step is to examine how the supply and demand for goods determine the accumulation of capital. In this first step, we assume that the labor force and technology are fixed. We then relax these assumptions by intro- ducing changes in the labor force later in this chapter and by introducing The Supply and Demand for Goods The supply and demand for goods played a central role in our static model of the closed economy in Chapter 3. The same is true for the Solow model By consid- ering the supply and demand for goods, we can see what determines how much output is produced at any given time and how this output is allocated among al- ternative uses The Solow growth model is named after economist Robert Solow and was developed in the 1950s and 1960s. In 1987 Solow won the Nobel Prize in economics for his work growth. The model was introduced in Robert M. Solow,"A Contribution to the Theory of Eco- nomic Growth, "Quarterly Journal of Economics(February 1956): 65-94 User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_cho7: Pg 181: 26798#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 181:26798#/eps at 100% *26798* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM technological progress affect the level of an economy’s output and its growth over time. In this chapter we analyze the roles of saving and population growth. In the next chapter we introduce technological progress.1 7-1 The Accumulation of Capital The Solow growth model is designed to show how growth in the capital stock, growth in the labor force, and advances in technology interact in an economy, and how they affect a nation’s total output of goods and services.We build this model in steps. Our first step is to examine how the supply and demand for goods determine the accumulation of capital. In this first step, we assume that the labor force and technology are fixed.We then relax these assumptions by intro￾ducing changes in the labor force later in this chapter and by introducing changes in technology in the next. The Supply and Demand for Goods The supply and demand for goods played a central role in our static model of the closed economy in Chapter 3.The same is true for the Solow model. By consid￾ering the supply and demand for goods, we can see what determines how much output is produced at any given time and how this output is allocated among al￾ternative uses. CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I | 181 1 The Solow growth model is named after economist Robert Solow and was developed in the 1950s and 1960s. In 1987 Solow won the Nobel Prize in economics for his work in economic growth.The model was introduced in Robert M. Solow, “A Contribution to the Theory of Eco￾nomic Growth,’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics (February 1956): 65–94. Income per Person Income per Person Country (in U.S. dollars) Country (in U.S. dollars) United States $31,910 China 3,550 Japan 25,170 Indonesia 2,660 Germany 23,510 India 2,230 Mexico 8,070 Pakistan 1,860 Russia 6,990 Bangladesh 1,530 Brazil 6,840 Nigeria 770 Source: World Bank. International Differences in the Standard of Living: 1999 table 7-1

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e 182 PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run The Supply of Goods and the Production Function The supply of goods in the Solow model is based on the now-familiar production function, which states that output depends on the capital stock and the labor force Y=F(K, L) Solow growth model assumes that the production function has constant re to scale. This assumption is often considered realistic, and as we will see shortly, it helps simplify the analysis. Recall that a production function has con- stant returns to scale if for any positive number z. That is, if we multiply both capital and labor by z,we also multiply the amount of output by z Production functions with constant returns to scale allow us to analyze all quantities in the economy relative to the size of the labor force. To see that this is true, set z=1/L in the preceding equation to obtain Y/L= F(K/L, 1) equation shows that the amount of output per worker Y/L is a function he amount of capital per worker K/L.(The number "1"is, of course, constant and thus can be ignored. )The assumption of constant returns to scale implies that the size of the economy-as measured by the number of workers-does not affect the relationship between output per worker and capi tal per worker Because the size of the economy does not matter, it will prove convenient to denote all quantities in per-worker terms. We designate these with lowercase let ters, so y=YL is output per worker, and k= k/L is capital per worker. We can then write the production function as where we define f(l )= F(k, 1). Figure 7-1 illustrates this production function The slope of this production function shows how much extra output a worker produces when given an extra unit of capital. This amount is the marginal prod uct of capital MPK. Mathematically, we write MPK=f(k+ 1)-f(k) Note that in Figure 7-1, as the amount of capital increases, the production func tion becomes fatter, indicating that the production function exhibits diminish- ing marginal product of capital. When k is low, the average worker has only a little capital to work with, so an extra unit of capital is very useful and produces lot of additional output When k is high, the average worker has a lot of capital, so an extra unit increases production only slightly. The Demand for Goods and the Consumption Function The demand for pods in the Solow model comes from consumption and investment. In other User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_ch07: Pg 182: 26799#/eps at 100sl ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 182:26799#/eps at 100% *26799* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM The Supply of Goods and the Production Function The supply of goods in the Solow model is based on the now-familiar production function, which states that output depends on the capital stock and the labor force: Y = F(K, L). The Solow growth model assumes that the production function has constant re￾turns to scale. This assumption is often considered realistic, and as we will see shortly, it helps simplify the analysis. Recall that a production function has con￾stant returns to scale if zY = F(zK, zL) for any positive number z.That is, if we multiply both capital and labor by z, we also multiply the amount of output by z. Production functions with constant returns to scale allow us to analyze all quantities in the economy relative to the size of the labor force.To see that this is true, set z = 1/L in the preceding equation to obtain Y/L = F(K/L, 1). This equation shows that the amount of output per worker Y/L is a function of the amount of capital per worker K/L. (The number “1” is, of course, constant and thus can be ignored.) The assumption of constant returns to scale implies that the size of the economy—as measured by the number of workers—does not affect the relationship between output per worker and capi￾tal per worker. Because the size of the economy does not matter, it will prove convenient to denote all quantities in per-worker terms.We designate these with lowercase let￾ters, so y = Y/L is output per worker, and k = K/L is capital per worker.We can then write the production function as y = f(k), where we define f(k) = F(k,1). Figure 7-1 illustrates this production function. The slope of this production function shows how much extra output a worker produces when given an extra unit of capital.This amount is the marginal prod￾uct of capital MPK. Mathematically, we write MPK = f(k + 1) − f(k). Note that in Figure 7-1, as the amount of capital increases, the production func￾tion becomes flatter, indicating that the production function exhibits diminish￾ing marginal product of capital. When k is low, the average worker has only a little capital to work with, so an extra unit of capital is very useful and produces a lot of additional output.When k is high, the average worker has a lot of capital, so an extra unit increases production only slightly. The Demand for Goods and the Consumption Function The demand for goods in the Solow model comes from consumption and investment. In other 182 | PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run

Worth: Mankiw Ecol how the amount of capital per worker k determines the amount of output per worker y=f(k) fu of capital: if k increases by nit, y increases by y MPK units he production function be comes flatter as k increases. in dicating diminishing marginal Per worker. k words,output per worker y is divided between consumption per worker and investment per worker i y This equation is the per-worker version of the national income accounts identity for an economy. Notice that it omits government purchases(which for present pur- poses we can ignore) and net exports(because we are assuming a closed economy The Solow model assumes that each year people save a fraction s of their in- ome and consume a fraction(1-s). We can express this idea with a consump tion function with the simple form where s, the saving rate, is a number between zero and one. Keep in mind that various government policies can potentially influence a nations saving rate,so one of our goals is to find what saving rate is desirable. For now, however, we just take the saving rate s as given. To see what this consumption function implies for investment, substitute (1-sy for c in the national income accounts identity Rearrange the terms to obtain This equation shows that investment equals saving, as we first saw in Chapter 3 Thus, the rate of saving s is also the fraction of output devoted to investment. User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_ ch07: Pg 183: 26800#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 183:26800#/eps at 100% *26800* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM words, output per worker y is divided between consumption per worker c and investment per worker i: y = c + i. This equation is the per-worker version of the national income accounts identity for an economy.Notice that it omits government purchases (which for present pur￾poses we can ignore) and net exports (because we are assuming a closed economy). The Solow model assumes that each year people save a fraction s of their in￾come and consume a fraction (1 − s).We can express this idea with a consump￾tion function with the simple form c = (1 − s)y, where s, the saving rate, is a number between zero and one. Keep in mind that various government policies can potentially influence a nation’s saving rate, so one of our goals is to find what saving rate is desirable. For now, however, we just take the saving rate s as given. To see what this consumption function implies for investment, substitute (1 − s)y for c in the national income accounts identity: y = (1 − s)y + i. Rearrange the terms to obtain i = sy. This equation shows that investment equals saving, as we first saw in Chapter 3. Thus, the rate of saving s is also the fraction of output devoted to investment. CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I | 183 figure 7-1 Output per worker, y MPK Capital per worker, k 1 Output, f(k) The Production Function The production function shows how the amount of capital per worker k determines the amount of output per worker y = f(k). The slope of the production function is the marginal product of capital: if k increases by 1 unit, y increases by MPK units. The production function be￾comes flatter as k increases, in￾dicating diminishing marginal product of capital

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e 184 PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run po Le have now introduced the two main ingredients of the Solow model-the duction function and the consumption functionwhich describe the econ- omy at any moment in time. For any given capital stock k, the production func tion y=f(ke)determines how much output the economy produces, and th saving rate s determines the allocation of that output between consumption and Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady State At any moment, the capital stock is a key determinant of the economy's output but the capital stock can change over time, and those changes can lead to eco- nomic growth. In particular, two forces influence the capital stock: investment and depreciation. Investment refers to the expenditure on new plant and equip- ment, and it causes the capital stock to rise. Depreciation refers to the wearing out of old capital, and it causes the capital stock to fall. Let's consider each of these In turn As we have already noted, investment per worker i equals sy. By substituting the production function for y, we can express investment per worker as a func tion of the capital stock per worker i=sf(ke) This equation relates the existing stock of capital k to the accumulation of new capital i. Figure 7-2 shows this relationship. This figure illustrates how, for any value of k, the amount of output is determined by the production function f(k) and the allocation of that output between consumption and saving is determined fi Output, Consumption, and In- vestment The saving rate s de- termines the allocation of Output, /( k) output between consumption o and investment. For any level capital k, output is f(k),invest- Output ment is sf(k), and consumption per worker is f(k)-sf(k) sf(k) Investment per worker per worker, k User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_cho7: Pg 184: 26801#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 184:26801#/eps at 100% *26801* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM We have now introduced the two main ingredients of the Solow model—the production function and the consumption function—which describe the econ￾omy at any moment in time. For any given capital stock k, the production func￾tion y = f(k) determines how much output the economy produces, and the saving rate s determines the allocation of that output between consumption and investment. Growth in the Capital Stock and the Steady State At any moment, the capital stock is a key determinant of the economy’s output, but the capital stock can change over time, and those changes can lead to eco￾nomic growth. In particular, two forces influence the capital stock: investment and depreciation. Investment refers to the expenditure on new plant and equip￾ment, and it causes the capital stock to rise. Depreciation refers to the wearing out of old capital, and it causes the capital stock to fall. Let’s consider each of these in turn. As we have already noted, investment per worker i equals sy. By substituting the production function for y, we can express investment per worker as a func￾tion of the capital stock per worker: i = sf(k). This equation relates the existing stock of capital k to the accumulation of new capital i. Figure 7-2 shows this relationship. This figure illustrates how, for any value of k, the amount of output is determined by the production function f(k), and the allocation of that output between consumption and saving is determined by the saving rate s. 184 | PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run figure 7-2 Output per worker, y y c Investment, sf(k) Output, f(k) i Capital per worker, k Consumption per worker Output per worker Investment per worker Output, Consumption, and In￾vestment The saving rate s de￾termines the allocation of output between consumption and investment. For any level of capital k, output is f(k), invest￾ment is sf(k), and consumption is f(k) − sf(k)

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I 185 figure 7-3 atIon Depreciation Depreciation A constant frac out every year. Depreciation is therefore proportional to the capital stock per worker, k To incorporate depreciation into the model, we assume that a certain fraction 8 of the capital stock wears out each year. Here 8(the lowercase Greek letter delta) is called the depreciation rate. For example, if capital lasts an average of 25 years, then the depreciation rate is 4 percent per year(6=0.04). The amount of capital that depreciates each year is ok. Figure 7-3 shows how the amount of de- preciation depends on the capital stock. We can express the impact of investment and depreciation on the capital stock with this equatio Change in Capital Stock= Investment- Depre where Ak is the change in the capital stock between one year and the next. Be- cause investment i equals sf(k), we can write this △k=f(k)-8k Figure 7-4 graphs the terms of this equation--investment and depreciation--for different levels of the capital stock k. The higher the capital stock, the greater the amounts of output and investment. Yet the higher the capital stock, the greater lso the amount of depreciation As Figure 7-4 shows, there is a single capital stock k* at which the amount of ivestment equals the amount of depreciation. If the economy ever finds itself at this level of the capital stock, the capital stock will not change because the two forces acting on it--investment and depreciation- just balance. That is, at k', Ak=0, so the capital stock k and output f(k) are steady over time(rather than growing or shrinking). We therefore call k' the steady-state level of capital The steady state is significant for two reasons. As we have just seen, an econ- my at the steady state will stay there. In addition, and just as important, an econ- omy not at the steady state will go there. That is, regardless of the level of capital User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_cho7: Pg 185: 26802#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 185:26802#/eps at 100% *26802* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM To incorporate depreciation into the model, we assume that a certain fraction d of the capital stock wears out each year. Here d (the lowercase Greek letter delta) is called the depreciation rate. For example, if capital lasts an average of 25 years, then the depreciation rate is 4 percent per year (d = 0.04).The amount of capital that depreciates each year is d k. Figure 7-3 shows how the amount of de￾preciation depends on the capital stock. We can express the impact of investment and depreciation on the capital stock with this equation: Change in Capital Stock = Investment − Depreciation Dk = i − d k, where Dk is the change in the capital stock between one year and the next. Be￾cause investment i equals sf(k), we can write this as Dk = sf(k) − d k. Figure 7-4 graphs the terms of this equation—investment and depreciation—for different levels of the capital stock k.The higher the capital stock, the greater the amounts of output and investment.Yet the higher the capital stock, the greater also the amount of depreciation. As Figure 7-4 shows, there is a single capital stock k* at which the amount of investment equals the amount of depreciation. If the economy ever finds itself at this level of the capital stock, the capital stock will not change because the two forces acting on it—investment and depreciation—just balance. That is, at k*, Dk = 0, so the capital stock k and output f(k) are steady over time (rather than growing or shrinking).We therefore call k* the steady-state level of capital. The steady state is significant for two reasons.As we have just seen, an econ￾omy at the steady state will stay there. In addition, and just as important, an econ￾omy not at the steady state will go there.That is, regardless of the level of capital CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I | 185 figure 7-3 Depreciation per worker, dk Depreciation, dk Capital per worker, k Depreciation A constant frac￾tion d of the capital stock wears out every year. Depreciation is therefore proportional to the capital stock

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e 186 PART 111 Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run figure 7-4 Investment, Depreciation, and the Depreciation, Steady State The steady-state level fca k“ is the level at which nvestment equals depreciation, in- icating that the amount of capit will not change over time. Below sf(k k", investment exceeds deprecia tion, so the capital stock grows Above k* investment is less than depreciation, so the capital stock per worker, k Capital stock Capital stock increases because decreases because investment exceeds per worker depreciation exceeds investment with which the economy begins, it ends up with the steady-state level of capital. In this sense, the steady state represents the long-run equilibrium of the economy To see why an economy always ends up at the steady state, suppose that the omy starts with less than the steady-state level of capital, such as level k, in Figure 7-4. In this case, the level of investment exceeds the amount of deprecia tion. Over time, the capital stock will rise and will continue to rise--along with output f(k)until it approaches the steady state k Similarly, suppose that the economy starts with more than the steady-state level of capital, such as level k2. In this case, investment is less than depreciation: capital is wearing out faster than it is being replaced. The capital stock will fal again approaching the steady-state level. Once the capital stock reaches the steady state, investment equals depreciation, and there is no pressure for the capi al stock to either increase or decrease Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example Let's use a numerical example to see how the Solow model works and how economy approaches the steady state. For this example, we assume that the duction function If you read the appendix to Chapter 3, you will recognize this as the Cobb-Douglas pre function with the parameter a equal to 1/2 User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_ ch07: Pg 186: 26803#/eps at 100sll ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 186:26803#/eps at 100% *26803* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM with which the economy begins, it ends up with the steady-state level of capital. In this sense, the steady state represents the long-run equilibrium of the economy. To see why an economy always ends up at the steady state, suppose that the economy starts with less than the steady-state level of capital, such as level k1 in Figure 7-4. In this case, the level of investment exceeds the amount of deprecia￾tion. Over time, the capital stock will rise and will continue to rise—along with output f(k)—until it approaches the steady state k*. Similarly, suppose that the economy starts with more than the steady-state level of capital, such as level k2. In this case, investment is less than depreciation: capital is wearing out faster than it is being replaced.The capital stock will fall, again approaching the steady-state level. Once the capital stock reaches the steady state, investment equals depreciation, and there is no pressure for the capi￾tal stock to either increase or decrease. Approaching the Steady State: A Numerical Example Let’s use a numerical example to see how the Solow model works and how the economy approaches the steady state. For this example, we assume that the pro￾duction function is2 Y = K1/2L1/2. 186 | PART III Growth Theory: The Economy in the Very Long Run figure 7-4 Steady-state level of capital per worker Capital stock decreases because depreciation exceeds investment. Capital stock increases because investment exceeds depreciation. dk2 Depreciation, dk Investment, sf(k) i 2 i* dk* i 1 k1 Investment and depreciation k* k2 Capital per worker, k dk1 Investment, Depreciation, and the Steady State The steady-state level of capital k* is the level at which investment equals depreciation, in￾dicating that the amount of capital will not change over time. Below k*, investment exceeds deprecia￾tion, so the capital stock grows. Above k*, investment is less than depreciation, so the capital stock shrinks. 2 If you read the appendix to Chapter 3, you will recognize this as the Cobb–Douglas production function with the parameter a equal to 1/2

Worth: Mankiw Economics 5e CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I 187 To derive the per-worker production function f(k), divide both sides of the pro- duction function by the labor force L YK1/2L1/2 L Rearrange to obtain K L Because y=Y/L and k=K/L, this becomes This equation can also be written as y=vk This form of the production function states that output per worker is equal to the square root of the amount of capital per worker. To complete the example, let's assume that 30 percent of output is saved(s 0.3), that 10 percent of the capital stock depreciates every year(6=0.1), and that the economy starts off with 4 units of capital per worker(k= 4). Given these lumbers, we can now examine what happens to this economy over time We begin by looking at the production and allocation of output in the first year. According to the production function, the 4 units of capital per worker produce 2 units of output per worker. Because 30 percent of output is saved and invested and 70 percent is consumed, i=0.6 and c=1. 4. Also, because 10 percent of the capital stock depreciates, 8k=0.4. With investment of 0.6 and deprecia tion of 0.4, the change in the capital stock is Ak=0. 2. The second year begins with 4.2 units of capital per worker Table 7-2 shows how the economy progresses year by year. Every year, new capital is added and output grows Over many years, the economy approaches a teady state with 9 units of capital per worker. In this steady state, investment of 0.9 exactly offsets depreciation of 0.9, so that the capital stock and output are no longer growing Following the progress of the economy for many years is one way to find the steady-state capital stock, but there is another way that requires fewer calcula tions. Recall that △k=f(k)-6k. This equation shows how k evolves over time. Because the steady state is(by definition) the value of k at which Ak=0, we know that 0=f(k*)一6k*, f(k*) User JoENA: Job EFFo1423:6264_ ch07: Pg 187: 26804#/eps at 100s ed,Feb13,20029:484M

User JOEWA:Job EFF01423:6264_ch07:Pg 187:26804#/eps at 100% *26804* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 9:48 AM To derive the per-worker production function f(k), divide both sides of the pro￾duction function by the labor force L: = . Rearrange to obtain = ( )1/2 . Because y = Y/L and k = K/L, this becomes y = k1/2. This equation can also be written as y = k. This form of the production function states that output per worker is equal to the square root of the amount of capital per worker. To complete the example, let’s assume that 30 percent of output is saved (s = 0.3), that 10 percent of the capital stock depreciates every year (d = 0.1), and that the economy starts off with 4 units of capital per worker (k = 4). Given these numbers, we can now examine what happens to this economy over time. We begin by looking at the production and allocation of output in the first year. According to the production function, the 4 units of capital per worker produce 2 units of output per worker. Because 30 percent of output is saved and invested and 70 percent is consumed, i = 0.6 and c = 1.4. Also, because 10 percent of the capital stock depreciates, d k = 0.4.With investment of 0.6 and deprecia￾tion of 0.4, the change in the capital stock is Dk = 0.2.The second year begins with 4.2 units of capital per worker. Table 7-2 shows how the economy progresses year by year. Every year, new capital is added and output grows. Over many years, the economy approaches a steady state with 9 units of capital per worker. In this steady state, investment of 0.9 exactly offsets depreciation of 0.9, so that the capital stock and output are no longer growing. Following the progress of the economy for many years is one way to find the steady-state capital stock, but there is another way that requires fewer calcula￾tions. Recall that Dk = sf(k) − d k. This equation shows how k evolves over time. Because the steady state is (by definition) the value of k at which Dk = 0, we know that 0 = sf(k*) − d k*, or, equivalently, = . s  d  k* f(k*) K L Y L K1/2L  1/2 L Y L CHAPTER 7 Economic Growth I | 187

点击下载完整版文档(PDF)VIP每日下载上限内不扣除下载券和下载次数;
按次数下载不扣除下载券;
24小时内重复下载只扣除一次;
顺序:VIP每日次数-->可用次数-->下载券;
共29页,试读已结束,阅读完整版请下载
相关文档

关于我们|帮助中心|下载说明|相关软件|意见反馈|联系我们

Copyright © 2008-现在 cucdc.com 高等教育资讯网 版权所有