当前位置:高等教育资讯网  >  中国高校课件下载中心  >  大学文库  >  浏览文档

《法学资料大全》(英文版)知识产权法和公司的界限

资源类别:文库,文档格式:PDF,文档页数:11,文件大小:96.95KB,团购合买
Arrow's disclosure paradox implies that information that is not afforded legal protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. This paper emphasizes the important relationship between the paradox of disclosure and the boundaries of the firm question. Only legally
点击下载完整版文档(PDF)

HARVARD LAW SCHOOL John M. olin Center for Law, Economics, and business Discussion Paper No 480 UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA LAW SCHOOL Law and Economics research Paper Series Research Paper No. 04-19 Intellectual Property law and the Boundaries of the firm Oren Bar-Gill Gideon Parchomovsky June 2004 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=559195 http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/

HARVARD LAW SCHOOL Intellectual Property Law and the Boundaries of the Firm Gideon Parchomovsky June 2004 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research. Network Paper Collection at John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business Discussion Paper No. 480 UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA LAW SCHOOL Law and Economics Research Paper Series Research Paper No. 04-19 http://ssrn.com/abstract=559195 http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/ Oren Bar-Gill

JEL Classification: D23. K11 L22 INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM Oren Bar-Gill and Gideon Parchomovsky Abstract Arrow's disclosure paradox implies that information that is not afforded legal protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. This paper emphasizes the important relationship between the paradox of disclosure and the boundaries of the firm question. Only legally protected inventions, i. e, patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the innovation process may not. Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance of economic principle, pre-patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of a single firm Keywords: Boundaries of the firm, disclosure paradox, intellectual property law Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law Economics and business University of Pennsylvania Law s This paper greatly benefited omments and criticisms by L k Omr Ben-Shahar. Yochai Benkler. James Chaim fershtman. Zohar liver hart. Josh Lemer Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico, Peter Siegelman, Omri Y adlin and seminar participants at boston university and penn we thank efrat procaccia for excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous financial support

JEL Classification: D23, K11, L22. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM Oren Bar-Gill* and Gideon Parchomovsky** Abstract Arrow’s disclosure paradox implies that information that is not afforded legal protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. This paper emphasizes the important relationship between the paradox of disclosure and the boundaries of the firm question. Only legally protected inventions, i.e., patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the innovation process may not. Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance of economic principle, pre-patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of a single firm. Keywords: Boundaries of the firm, disclosure paradox, intellectual property law. * Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business. ** University of Pennsylvania Law School. This paper greatly benefited from comments and criticisms by Ian Ayres, Lucian Bebchuk, Omri Ben-Shahar, Yochai Benkler, James Bessen, Chaim Fershtman, Zohar Goshen, Oliver Hart, Josh Lerner, Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Porat, Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico, Peter Siegelman, Omri Yadlin and seminar participants at Boston University and Penn. We thank Efrat Procaccia for excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous financial support

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM Oren Bar-Gill' and Gideon Parchomovsky C 2004 Oren Bar-Gill and Gideon Parchomovsky. All rights reserved 1. Introduction Innovation is crucial in technology intensive markets. For many firms inventions are a critical factor of production. Examples of downstream firms purchasing or licensing technology from upstream innovators are common(see, e.g., Arora et al., 2001). Indeed both Transaction Costs Economics (TCE)and the property rights Theory(prt)suggest that in many cases, efficiency requires that the inventive process-from the conception of an idea through its development and ultimate commercialization-be divided among several firms(Williamson, 1975; Aghion and Tirole, 1994; Arora et al., 2001; Arora and Merges, 2004) The question thus becomes which stages of the inventive hould be integrated in a single firm and which should be divided among different firms and traded on the market? We argue that the theoretic investigation of the optimal boundary between firm and market cannot be carried out in a legal vacuum. Ideally, only the economic considerations identified by TCE and Prt should affect the "make or buy"decision. In practice, however, law imposes an important constraint on the economic balance between firms and markets Critically, the law defines which stages of the inventive process are amenable to market trading. As Arrow (1962) recognized, information that is not afforded legal protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. Absent legal protection, the information holder is in a bind in order to sell the information she must disclose it to the potential buyer, but once she does, she has nothing left to sell. This paper emphasizes the important relationship between Arrow's paradox of disclosure and the question of the boundaries of information intensive firms. Only legally protected inventions,i.e patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the innovation process may not Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance of economic principle, pre- patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of a single firm Intellectual property law is therefore an important factor influencing the boundary between the firm and the market. When it is more difficult to obtain a patent more Innovative activity mus integrated within a single firm (or be forgone altogether) Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law Economics and business University of Pennsylvania Law s This paper greatly benefited omments and criticisms by lan ayres, Lucian bebchul Ben-Shahar. Yochai Benkler. James Chaim Fershtman. Zohar Goshen. Oliver Hart. Josh L Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico Siegelman, Omri Y adlin and seminar participants at boston university and penn we thank efrat procaccia or excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous

INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM Oren Bar-Gill* and Gideon Parchomovsky** © 2004 Oren Bar-Gill and Gideon Parchomovsky. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Innovation is crucial in technology intensive markets. For many firms inventions are a critical factor of production. Examples of downstream firms purchasing or licensing technology from upstream innovators are common (see, e.g., Arora et al., 2001). Indeed, both Transaction Costs Economics (TCE) and the Property Rights Theory (PRT) suggest that in many cases, efficiency requires that the inventive process—from the conception of an idea through its development and ultimate commercialization—be divided among several firms (Williamson, 1975; Aghion and Tirole, 1994; Arora et al., 2001; Arora and Merges, 2004). The question thus becomes which stages of the inventive process should be integrated in a single firm and which should be divided among different firms and traded on the market? We argue that the theoretic investigation of the optimal boundary between firm and market cannot be carried out in a legal vacuum. Ideally, only the economic considerations identified by TCE and PRT should affect the “make or buy” decision. In practice, however, law imposes an important constraint on the economic balance between firms and markets. Critically, the law defines which stages of the inventive process are amenable to market trading. As Arrow (1962) recognized, information that is not afforded legal protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. Absent legal protection, the information holder is in a bind: in order to sell the information, she must disclose it to the potential buyer, but once she does, she has nothing left to sell. This paper emphasizes the important relationship between Arrow’s paradox of disclosure and the question of the boundaries of information intensive firms. Only legally protected inventions, i.e., patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the innovation process may not. Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance of economic principle, pre￾patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of a single firm. Intellectual property law is therefore an important factor influencing the boundary between the firm and the market. When it is more difficult to obtain a patent more innovative activity must be integrated within a single firm (or be forgone altogether). * Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business. ** University of Pennsylvania Law School. This paper greatly benefited from comments and criticisms by Ian Ayres, Lucian Bebchuk, Omri Ben-Shahar, Yochai Benkler, James Bessen, Chaim Fershtman, Zohar Goshen, Oliver Hart, Josh Lerner, Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Porat, Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico, Peter Siegelman, Omri Yadlin and seminar participants at Boston University and Penn. We thank Efrat Procaccia for excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous financial support. 1

Conversely, when the legal requirements of patentability are relaxed, as they have been in recent years, a shift of activity from firms to the market should be expected. Trade secret law and the legal treatment of covenants not to compete similarly affect firm boundaries by determining the allocation of entitlements between firms and employees The implications of innovation for the make-or-buy decision have been highlighted by Williamson(1975), Teece(1986, 1988), and Aghion and Tirole(1994) Previous work has also recognized the relevance of appropriability and intellectual property law to various contractual, strategic and organizational questions in technology ntensive industries. The importance of appropriability and the relationship between appropriability and intellectual property rights was first emphasized by Teece(1986) Arora et al. (2001) highlight the difficulty in contracting over tacit knowledge and know how(ch. 5), noting"the role of patents in facilitating transactions in technology. (p. 262 Gans and Stern(2003a)consider the implications of the disclosure paradox for entrepreneur's choice of a commercialization strategy, recognizing the role of intellectual property in solving the paradox. In a couple of related empirical studies, these authors show how intellectual property rights and appropriability problems affect the timing of cooperation/licensing(Gans and Stern, 2003b)as well as the choice of a start-up innovator between competition or cooperation (i.e. contracting) with more established firms(Gans et al., 2000). Another recent empirical study shows that technologies developed by firms operating in countries with weak intellectual property rights are used more internally(Zhao, 2003). Anton and Yao, in a series of papers, explore the implications of and the strategic responses to the disclosure paradox, caused by imperfect legal protection of pre-patent ideas(Anton and Yao, 1994, 2000, 2001, 2003a, 2003b, see also Bhattacharya and Guriev, 2004 Finally, Dan Burk and Ashish Arora and Robert merges, in two recent contributions, explicitly focus on the interrelations between intellectual property law and the boundaries of the firm question. Burk(2004 ) focuses on the implications of the theor of the firm for intellectual property law. While we focus on the reverse implications of intellectual property law for the theory of the firm, Burks insights are clearly important for our analysis. Arora and Merges(2004)show that stronger intellectual property rights support smaller firms that specialize in the supply of technology inputs. The analysis in Arora and Merges(2004) can be interpreted as proposing one way to minimize the costs associated with the disclosure paradox--through intellectual property rights in complementary assets(see also Merges, 2000; Arora et al., 2001). Our focus, on the other hand, is on intellectual property rights in the core informational asset. More generally, the preconditions for the creation of legally enforceable intellectual property rights. On while the literature has focused on the strength of intellectual property rights, we focus on The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a simple model, formalizing the role of intellectual property law as a constraint on the optimal level of vertical integration in technology-intensive industries. Section 3 draws the broader implications of the model for the structure and organization of technology intensive industries, discussing firm size, the role of research universities, r&d alliances and joint ventures, and R&D financing. Section 4 argues that intellectual property law affects not only the feasibility of the market option but also the feasibility of the firm option. Section 5 concludes

Conversely, when the legal requirements of patentability are relaxed, as they have been in recent years, a shift of activity from firms to the market should be expected. Trade secret law and the legal treatment of covenants not to compete similarly affect firm boundaries by determining the allocation of entitlements between firms and employees. The implications of innovation for the make-or-buy decision have been highlighted by Williamson (1975), Teece (1986, 1988), and Aghion and Tirole (1994). Previous work has also recognized the relevance of appropriability and intellectual property law to various contractual, strategic and organizational questions in technology￾intensive industries. The importance of appropriability and the relationship between appropriability and intellectual property rights was first emphasized by Teece (1986). Arora et al. (2001) highlight the difficulty in contracting over tacit knowledge and know￾how (ch. 5), noting “the role of patents in facilitating transactions in technology.” (p. 262) Gans and Stern (2003a) consider the implications of the disclosure paradox for an entrepreneur’s choice of a commercialization strategy, recognizing the role of intellectual property in solving the paradox. In a couple of related empirical studies, these authors show how intellectual property rights and appropriability problems affect the timing of cooperation/licensing (Gans and Stern, 2003b) as well as the choice of a start-up innovator between competition or cooperation (i.e. contracting) with more established firms (Gans et al., 2000). Another recent empirical study shows that technologies developed by firms operating in countries with weak intellectual property rights are used more internally (Zhao, 2003). Anton and Yao, in a series of papers, explore the implications of and the strategic responses to the disclosure paradox, caused by imperfect legal protection of pre-patent ideas (Anton and Yao, 1994, 2000, 2001, 2003a, 2003b; see also Bhattacharya and Guriev, 2004). Finally, Dan Burk and Ashish Arora and Robert Merges, in two recent contributions, explicitly focus on the interrelations between intellectual property law and the boundaries of the firm question. Burk (2004) focuses on the implications of the theory of the firm for intellectual property law. While we focus on the reverse implications of intellectual property law for the theory of the firm, Burk’s insights are clearly important for our analysis. Arora and Merges (2004) show that stronger intellectual property rights support smaller firms that specialize in the supply of technology inputs. The analysis in Arora and Merges (2004) can be interpreted as proposing one way to minimize the costs associated with the disclosure paradox—through intellectual property rights in complementary assets (see also Merges, 2000; Arora et al., 2001). Our focus, on the other hand, is on intellectual property rights in the core informational asset. More generally, while the literature has focused on the strength of intellectual property rights, we focus on the preconditions for the creation of legally enforceable intellectual property rights. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a simple model, formalizing the role of intellectual property law as a constraint on the optimal level of vertical integration in technology-intensive industries. Section 3 draws the broader implications of the model for the structure and organization of technology￾intensive industries, discussing firm size, the role of research universities, R&D alliances and joint ventures, and R&D financing. Section 4 argues that intellectual property law affects not only the feasibility of the market option but also the feasibility of the firm option. Section 5 concludes. 2

2. Model We formalize the effect of intellectual property law on the boundaries of the firm question using a simple PRT model. Consider an inventor (D)and a developer(D).An innovation process combining the efforts of both I and d produces a value V(i, d ) where i denotes I's investment and d denotes D's investment. The value of Is outside option is v(O, and the value of D's outside option is v(d). Assuming V(i, d)>v(+v(d) the first-best investment levels are given by max(v(i, d)-i-dy Non-verifiability of investments implies contractual incompleteness that restricts the parties' options to a choice between integration(Int) and non-integration(NInt) Under the integration option, D owns the product of Is effort. Consequently, I does not enjoy any of the value created by her efforts, and is motivated to invest only by the soft incentives created within the integrated firm. Let i=i denote I's investment under integration.D's investment under integration is given by: d/m=argmax(v(, d)=d) Total net payoffs under integration are: n(i imn, d m)=v(i im, dm)-ilmedi The second alternative is non-integration(NInt), whereby I retains control over her invention, and can sell it to D ex post. The non-integration option, however, is not al ways available. Given the disclosure paradox, the NInt option is feasible only if the law recognizes the product of I's efforts as intellectual property, thus affording it legal protection. If such IP protection is granted, ex post the parties will negotiate a transfer of the legal rights from I to D. Assuming Nash bargaining, the ex post surplus V(i, d)-v(i-v(d) is equally divided between the parties. Hence, Is ex post payoff is (i, d)=v(+v(i, d)-v(i-v(dl, and D's ex post payoff is r (i, d)=r (d)+ V(i, d)-vG-v(d]. The investment levels are given by iMin =argmax/'(, d)-n and d n =argmax(r(, d )-d.We assume the existence of a unique equilibrium m, d m ) Total net payoffs under integration are We can state the following Proposition: When n( in, d m )>n (i n, d m), if Is invention is legally protected, ther non-integration will obtain, but if I's invention is not legally protected, integration will obtain i The PRT framework employed in this section borrows from Hart(1995)and from Aghion and Tirole (1994 ). A TCE model could readily be developed to capture the same effect. Theoretically, the reverse form of integration, where I owns the combined product of both parties'efforts is also possible. Following Aghion and Tirole(1994), we choose not to focus on this form of integration, which can be ruled out if I is cash constrained increased/decreased salary and other monetary and non-monetary benefits and costs conferred by the inventor's managers and peers. See, e.g., Williamson(1975). If the value of the final output v is verifiable, then Is employment contract in the Int case can be made contingent on V, thus improving Is incentive

2. Model We formalize the effect of intellectual property law on the boundaries of the firm question using a simple PRT model.1 Consider an inventor (I) and a developer (D). An innovation process combining the efforts of both I and D produces a value V(i,d), where i denotes I’s investment and d denotes D’s investment. The value of I’s outside option is , and the value of D’s outside option is . Assuming , the first-best investment levels are given by v (i) I v (d) D V (i,d) v (i) v (d) I D > + V i d i d i d max ( , ) − − , . Non-verifiability of investments implies contractual incompleteness that restricts the parties’ options to a choice between integration (Int) and non-integration (NInt). Under the integration option, D owns the product of I’s effort.2 Consequently, I does not enjoy any of the value created by her efforts, and is motivated to invest only by the soft incentives created within the integrated firm. 3 Let denote I’s investment under integration. D’s investment under integration is given by: i i Int = ˆ d V i d d d Int = argmax (ˆ, ) − . Total net payoffs under integration are: ( ) ( ) Int Int Int Int Int Int Π i , . d =V i ,d − i − d The second alternative is non-integration (NInt), whereby I retains control over her invention, and can sell it to D ex post. The non-integration option, however, is not always available. Given the disclosure paradox, the NInt option is feasible only if the law recognizes the product of I’s efforts as intellectual property, thus affording it legal protection. If such IP protection is granted, ex post the parties will negotiate a transfer of the legal rights from I to D. Assuming Nash bargaining, the ex post surplus V (i,d) v (i) v (d) is equally divided between the parties. Hence, I’s ex post payoff is I D − − ( , ) ( ) [ ( , ) ( ) ( )] 2 1 i d v i V i d v i v d I I I D π = + − − , and D’s ex post payoff is ( , ) ( ) [ ( , ) ( ) ( )] 2 1 i d v d V i d v i v d D D I D π = + − − . The investment levels are given by: i i d i I i NInt = argmax π ( , ) − and d i d d D d NInt = argmax π ( , ) − . We assume the existence of a unique equilibrium ( ) NInt NInt i ,d . Total net payoffs under integration are: ( ) ( ) NInt NInt NInt NInt NInt NInt Π i , . d =V i ,d − i − d We can now state the following: Proposition: When ( ) ( ) NInt NInt Int Int Π i ,d > Π i ,d , if I’s invention is legally protected, then non-integration will obtain, but if I’s invention is not legally protected, integration will obtain. 1 The PRT framework employed in this section borrows from Hart (1995) and from Aghion and Tirole (1994). A TCE model could readily be developed to capture the same effect. 2 Theoretically, the reverse form of integration, where I owns the combined product of both parties’ efforts, is also possible. Following Aghion and Tirole (1994), we choose not to focus on this form of integration, which can be ruled out if I is cash constrained. 3 These soft incentives include the possibility of promotion/demotion (or even dismissal), increased/decreased salary and other monetary and non-monetary benefits and costs conferred by the inventor’s managers and peers. See, e.g., Williamson (1975). If the value of the final output V is verifiable, then I’s employment contract in the Int case can be made contingent on V, thus improving I’s incentives. 3

An integrated firm cannot replicate the "high-powered incentives" provided under non-integration, hence i" >i(Williamson, 1985). Accordingly, the non-integration option is more efficient when the marginal importance of I's investment is large enough relative to D's investment( Grossman and Hart, 1986). But if the law does not protect the product of I's investment, the non-integration option is precluded by the disclosure paradox, forcing the parties to integrate More generally, the Proposition implies that if I's invention is not legally protected integration will necessarily occur, and that such integration will be inefficient when n(G int, d n n(i in, d in ) The welfare implications of this result depend on the size of the set of cases where non-integration is superior to integration. Characterizing this set of cases has been and remains the main task of the boundaries of the firm literature. The welfare loss attributed to imperfect intellectual property rights would be small, if the law would refuse to protect I's invention only when integration is the optimal organizational structure. Unfortunately, legal rules are not calibrated to the economic factors that determine the relative efficiency of integration versus non-integration. In fact, the legal distinction between protected and unprotected inventions is probably orthogonal to the economic choice between integration and non-integration Finally, the Proposition assumes that the integration option is al ways feasible This assumption is not always valid. Specifically, when the law precludes the non- integration option and the inefficiency of forced integration is sufficiently large, th innovation project might be abandoned altogether, introducing yet another welfare cost 3. Implications The simple model developed in Section 2 has broad implications for the structure and organization of technology-intensive industries 1)Basic research in commercial firms: Significant R&D at the very fundamental level is being done within commercial firms such as IBM and Motorola. while theory does not preclude the efficiency of such integration, there is good reason to believe that basic esearch should not generally be integrated with commercial enterprise. The absence of legal protection for pre-patent innovation is arguably a contributing factor for the integration of such innovation within firms that specialize in development and commercialization 2)Research universities: A major role of universities is to foster basic research at the pre patent stages. For present purposes, a research university is an organization, not unlike a commercial firm, that can provide soft incentives for r&d activities that do not result in a legally protected invention. In addition, public subsidization of basic research in While straightforward non-integration and trade are precluded by the disclosure paradox, in some cases the non-integration option cannot be completely ruled out. Even in the absence of legal protection of her invention, the inventor may be able to extract some value from the developer. See Teece(1986), Anton and Yao(1994, 2002), Arora (2001), Zucker et al.(2001), and Biais and Perotti(2003). Also, in certain contexts innovators are driven by non-pecuniary motives and are thus more willing to share ideas across firm boundaries. See Lessig(2001), and Benkler(2002) Regarding the feasibility of the integration option see also Section 4 belov

An integrated firm cannot replicate the “high-powered incentives” provided under non-integration, hence (Williamson, 1985). Accordingly, the non-integration option is more efficient when the marginal importance of I’s investment is large enough relative to D’s investment (Grossman and Hart, 1986). But if the law does not protect the product of I’s investment, the non-integration option is precluded by the disclosure paradox, forcing the parties to integrate. NInt Int i > i 4 More generally, the Proposition implies that if I’s invention is not legally protected integration will necessarily occur, and that such integration will be inefficient when ( ) ( ) NInt NInt Int Int Π i ,d > Π i ,d . The welfare implications of this result depend on the size of the set of cases where non-integration is superior to integration. Characterizing this set of cases has been and remains the main task of the boundaries of the firm literature. The welfare loss attributed to imperfect intellectual property rights would be small, if the law would refuse to protect I’s invention only when integration is the optimal organizational structure. Unfortunately, legal rules are not calibrated to the economic factors that determine the relative efficiency of integration versus non-integration. In fact, the legal distinction between protected and unprotected inventions is probably orthogonal to the economic choice between integration and non-integration. Finally, the Proposition assumes that the integration option is always feasible. This assumption is not always valid. Specifically, when the law precludes the non￾integration option and the inefficiency of forced integration is sufficiently large, the innovation project might be abandoned altogether, introducing yet another welfare cost.5 3. Implications The simple model developed in Section 2 has broad implications for the structure and organization of technology-intensive industries: 1) Basic research in commercial firms: Significant R&D at the very fundamental level is being done within commercial firms such as IBM and Motorola. While theory does not preclude the efficiency of such integration, there is good reason to believe that basic research should not generally be integrated with commercial enterprise. The absence of legal protection for pre-patent innovation is arguably a contributing factor for the integration of such innovation within firms that specialize in development and commercialization. 2) Research universities: A major role of universities is to foster basic research at the pre￾patent stages. For present purposes, a research university is an organization, not unlike a commercial firm, that can provide soft incentives for R&D activities that do not result in a legally protected invention. In addition, public subsidization of basic research in 4 While straightforward non-integration and trade are precluded by the disclosure paradox, in some cases the non-integration option cannot be completely ruled out. Even in the absence of legal protection of her invention, the inventor may be able to extract some value from the developer. See Teece (1986), Anton and Yao (1994, 2002), Arora (2001), Zucker et al. (2001), and Biais and Perotti (2003). Also, in certain contexts innovators are driven by non-pecuniary motives and are thus more willing to share ideas across firm boundaries. See Lessig (2001), and Benkler (2002). 5 Regarding the feasibility of the integration option see also Section 4 below. 4

universities can be understood as a response to imperfect intellectual property rights. If the law does not protect an invention, then this invention may be developed within an integrated firm, or when the inefficiency of the integration option is sufficiently large the invention might not be developed at all. Public funding may be the only way--other than extending the scope of intellectual property-to ensure the development of Inventions 3)R&d alliances: In the new, technology-intensive economy R&D alliances are an increasingly common phenomenon. Given imperfect intellectual property rights, the organizational structure of an alliance must respond to problems akin to those underlying the disclosure paradox. Specifically, the two partner firms are faced with a choice between a contract joint venture, where the object of the alliance becomes the subject of an explicit contract, and an equity joint venture, where the two partner firms incorporate separate entity that will conduct r&D activities. When the law does not protect the stage of the inventive process that is the subject of the alliance, the partner firms might be forced to choose a less efficient equity structure. 6 4)R&D financing The disclosure paradox that plagues the relationship between potential sellers and buyers of pre-patent inventions might also prevent efficient external financing of the pre-patent stages of the inventive process(see Aghion and Tirole, 1994). Excessive integration to enable internal financing might follow. More generally the locus of innovation might inefficiently shift to larger firms capable of internal financing 4. Employee Mobility As argued above, intellectual property law affects the viability of the market option, thus influencing the boundary between firm and market. But the market option is not the only organizational form affected by the law. The viability of the firm, as an alternative to the market, also depends on the law's willingness to protect intangible Under the PRt, a firm is a collection of assets over which a manager enjoys residual control rights. Specifically, the firm controls employees' access to and use of its assets(Hart, 1995). With traditional, tangible assets unauthorized use can be easily prevented by restricting physical access to the asset. With intangible assets, however, control of access to the asset is often meaningless. When an employee, through initial access, acquires certain knowledge, denial of future access will not erase this knowledge Access control is thus powerless to prevent unauthorized use, specifically use by the employee after she moves to another firm. If the law does not protect the intangible asset, the firm loses all control over the asset; and in essence, the knowledge ceases to be the The implications of weak intellectual property rights for the organization of r&D alliances have been previously recognized. See Oxley(1997, 1999), Anand and Khanna(2000), Sampson(2004), Majewski and williamson(2003) In fact, legal protection is also a prerequisite for tangible assets. The firms ability to restrict physical access to tangible assets relies on the laws recognition of property rights in these assets

universities can be understood as a response to imperfect intellectual property rights. If the law does not protect an invention, then this invention may be developed within an integrated firm, or when the inefficiency of the integration option is sufficiently large the invention might not be developed at all. Public funding may be the only way—other than extending the scope of intellectual property—to ensure the development of such inventions. 3) R&D alliances: In the new, technology-intensive economy R&D alliances are an increasingly common phenomenon. Given imperfect intellectual property rights, the organizational structure of an alliance must respond to problems akin to those underlying the disclosure paradox. Specifically, the two partner firms are faced with a choice between a contract joint venture, where the object of the alliance becomes the subject of an explicit contract, and an equity joint venture, where the two partner firms incorporate a separate entity that will conduct R&D activities. When the law does not protect the stage of the inventive process that is the subject of the alliance, the partner firms might be forced to choose a less efficient equity structure.6 4) R&D financing: The disclosure paradox that plagues the relationship between potential sellers and buyers of pre-patent inventions might also prevent efficient external financing of the pre-patent stages of the inventive process (see Aghion and Tirole, 1994). Excessive integration to enable internal financing might follow. More generally the locus of innovation might inefficiently shift to larger firms capable of internal financing. 4. Employee Mobility As argued above, intellectual property law affects the viability of the market option, thus influencing the boundary between firm and market. But the market option is not the only organizational form affected by the law. The viability of the firm, as an alternative to the market, also depends on the law’s willingness to protect intangible assets. Under the PRT, a firm is a collection of assets over which a manager enjoys residual control rights. Specifically, the firm controls employees’ access to and use of its assets (Hart, 1995). With traditional, tangible assets unauthorized use can be easily prevented by restricting physical access to the asset. With intangible assets, however, control of access to the asset is often meaningless. When an employee, through initial access, acquires certain knowledge, denial of future access will not erase this knowledge. Access control is thus powerless to prevent unauthorized use, specifically use by the employee after she moves to another firm. If the law does not protect the intangible asset, the firm loses all control over the asset; and, in essence, the knowledge ceases to be the firm’s asset.7 6 The implications of weak intellectual property rights for the organization of R&D alliances have been previously recognized. See Oxley (1997, 1999), Anand and Khanna (2000), Sampson (2004), Majewski and Williamson (2003). 7 In fact, legal protection is also a prerequisite for tangible assets. The firm’s ability to restrict physical access to tangible assets relies on the law’s recognition of property rights in these assets. 5

Patent law provides one channel for protecting intangible assets. Kim and Marschke(2001)argue that firms patent to reduce the incidence of employees leaving to start or join rival firms(see also Merges, 1999). But not all intangible assets qualify for patent protection, and some lack the minimal degree of verifiability necessary for patent protection. The law provides alternative channels for controlling the use of intangible assets by employees. Trade secret law is one such channel(Merges et al., 2003). Another channel focuses on direct limitations on employee mobility, through the law governing non-compete clauses. See Aghion and Tirole(1994), Gilson(1999), Baccara and Razin (2002), Hellmann(2002)and Burk(2004) The theory of the firm literature presumes the viability of both the market option and the firm alternative, and proceeds to study the optimal choice between these two options. The viability of both options, however, depends on the law's willingness to Dgnize property rights in intangibles. Sections 2 and 3 argued that without such property rights innovation that should have ideally been mediated by the market would be forced into the confines of a single firm. The present section suggested that even the firm haven relies on some form of legal protection Intellectual property law directly affects the structure and organization of technology-intensive industries by imposing an often binding constraint on the choice between integration and non-integration. This characterization of legally determined appropriability as a constraint on organizational choice provides a simple theoretical link between the growing literature on the organization of innovation and the conventional TCE and Property Rights theories of the firm The predictions of our model sit well with the empirical evidence on the relationship between legal and organizational variations. Recently intellectual property law has made it easier to obtain patent protection for embryonic inventions(see, e. g Mazzoleni and Nelson, 1998). The increasing importance of small specialty r&D firms (see, e.g., Arora and Merges, 2004), the increase in the number of university patents (described, for example, in Arora et al., 2001, sec. 10.4), and the prevalence of non- integration, non-equity research alliances and joint-ventures(see, e.g., Sampson, 2004 can be at least partially explained by the relaxation of the legal patentability requirements. Similarly, the growth of the venture capital industry arguably was stimulated by the law's increasing willingness to grant intellectual property rights to small research start-ups-the archetypal user of venture capital funding. Looking our analysIs y identifying the different channels through which intellectual property law affects the boundaries between firm and market, suggests a range of testable predictions that we hope will motivate future empirical work 6

Patent law provides one channel for protecting intangible assets. Kim and Marschke (2001) argue that firms patent to reduce the incidence of employees leaving to start or join rival firms (see also Merges, 1999). But not all intangible assets qualify for patent protection, and some lack the minimal degree of verifiability necessary for patent protection. The law provides alternative channels for controlling the use of intangible assets by employees. Trade secret law is one such channel (Merges et al., 2003). Another channel focuses on direct limitations on employee mobility, through the law governing non-compete clauses. See Aghion and Tirole (1994), Gilson (1999), Baccara and Razin (2002), Hellmann (2002) and Burk (2004). The theory of the firm literature presumes the viability of both the market option and the firm alternative, and proceeds to study the optimal choice between these two options. The viability of both options, however, depends on the law’s willingness to recognize property rights in intangibles. Sections 2 and 3 argued that without such property rights innovation that should have ideally been mediated by the market would be forced into the confines of a single firm. The present section suggested that even the firm haven relies on some form of legal protection. 5. Conclusion Intellectual property law directly affects the structure and organization of technology-intensive industries by imposing an often binding constraint on the choice between integration and non-integration. This characterization of legally determined appropriability as a constraint on organizational choice provides a simple theoretical link between the growing literature on the organization of innovation and the conventional TCE and Property Rights theories of the firm. The predictions of our model sit well with the empirical evidence on the relationship between legal and organizational variations. Recently intellectual property law has made it easier to obtain patent protection for embryonic inventions (see, e.g., Mazzoleni and Nelson, 1998). The increasing importance of small specialty R&D firms (see, e.g., Arora and Merges, 2004), the increase in the number of university patents (described, for example, in Arora et al., 2001, sec. 10.4), and the prevalence of non￾integration, non-equity research alliances and joint-ventures (see, e.g., Sampson, 2004) can be at least partially explained by the relaxation of the legal patentability requirements. Similarly, the growth of the venture capital industry arguably was stimulated by the law’s increasing willingness to grant intellectual property rights to small research start-ups—the archetypal user of venture capital funding. Looking forward, our analysis, by identifying the different channels through which intellectual property law affects the boundaries between firm and market, suggests a range of testable predictions that we hope will motivate future empirical work. 6

Aghion, Philippe and Tirole, Jean(1994),"The Management of Innovation, " Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 1185-1209 Anand, Bharat N. and Khanna, Tarun(2000),"The Structure of Licensing Contracts al of Industrial Econ 48.103-135 Anton, James J and Yao, Dennis A(1994),"Expropriation and Inventions: Appropriable Rents in the Absence of Property Rights, American Economic Review, 84, 190- 209 Anton, James J and Yao, Dennis A(2000),"Little Patents and Big Secrets: Managing Intellectual Property, mimeo, University of Pennsylvania Anton, James J and Yao, Dennis A.(2002),"The Sale of Ideas: Strategic Disclosure Property Rights, and Contracting, forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies Anton, James J and Yao, Dennis A(2003a),"Entrepreneurs and New Ideas, mimeo rivers ity of Pennsylvania Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A(2003b),Attracting Skeptical Buyers, mimeo, University of Pennsylvania Aror. Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy(MIT Press, for Arora, Ashish, Fosfuri, Andrea and Gambardella, Alfonso(2001), Markets for ora, Ashish and Merges, Robert P.(2004),Specialized Supply Firms, Pro and Firm Boundaries, "Industrial and Corporate Change, 13, 451- operty Rights Arrow, Kenneth J.(1962),"Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources fo Invention, " in Richard R. Nelson(ed ) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity 609-625 Baccara, Mariagiovanna and Razin, ronny (2002),"From Thought to Practice Appropriation and Endogenous Market Structure with Imperfect Intellectual Property Rights, mimeo, Princeton University Benkler, Yochai(2002),"Coase's Penguin, or, Linux and The Theory of the Firm, Yale Law Journal. 112. 369-446 Bhattacharya, Sudipto, and Guriev, Sergei(2004),"Knowledge Disclosure, Patents, and Optimal Organization of Research and Development, mimeo, Princeton University Biais, Bruno and Perotti, Enrico(2003),"Entrepreneurs and New Ideas, mimeo Toulouse University Burk, Dan L(2004), "Intellectual Property and the Firm, University of Chicago La Review,71,3-20. Gans, Joshua S, Hsu, David H, and Stern, Scott (2000),When Does Start-Up Innovation Spur the Gale of Creative Destruction? "NBER Working Paper No W7851 Gans, Joshua S. and Stern, Scott(2003a),The Product Market and the Market for Ideas:Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs, " Research Policy,32,333-350 Gans, Joshua S and Stern, Scott(2003b),"The Impact of Uncertain IP Rights on the Market for Ideas: Evidence from Patent Grant Delays, mimeo, Northwestern University

References Aghion, Philippe and Tirole, Jean (1994), “The Management of Innovation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 1185-1209. Anand, Bharat N. and Khanna, Tarun (2000), “The Structure of Licensing Contracts,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 103-135. Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (1994), “Expropriation and Inventions: Appropriable Rents in the Absence of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 84, 190- 209. Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2000), “Little Patents and Big Secrets: Managing Intellectual Property,” mimeo, University of Pennsylvania. Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2002), “The Sale of Ideas: Strategic Disclosure, Property Rights, and Contracting,” forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies. Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2003a), “Entrepreneurs and New Ideas,” mimeo, University of Pennsylvania. Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2003b), “Attracting Skeptical Buyers,” mimeo, University of Pennsylvania. Arora, Ashish, Fosfuri, Andrea and Gambardella, Alfonso (2001), Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy (MIT Press). Arora, Ashish and Merges, Robert P. (2004), “Specialized Supply Firms, Property Rights and Firm Boundaries,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 13, 451-475. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,” in Richard R. Nelson (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, 609-625. Baccara, Mariagiovanna and Razin, Ronny (2002), “From Thought to Practice: Appropriation and Endogenous Market Structure with Imperfect Intellectual Property Rights,” mimeo, Princeton University. Benkler, Yochai (2002), “Coase’s Penguin, or, Linux and The Theory of the Firm,” Yale Law Journal, 112, 369-446. Bhattacharya, Sudipto, and Guriev, Sergei (2004), “Knowledge Disclosure, Patents, and Optimal Organization of Research and Development,” mimeo, Princeton University. Biais, Bruno and Perotti, Enrico (2003), “Entrepreneurs and New Ideas,” mimeo, Toulouse University. Burk, Dan L. (2004), “Intellectual Property and the Firm,” University of Chicago Law Review, 71, 3-20. Gans, Joshua S., Hsu, David H., and Stern, Scott (2000), “When Does Start-Up Innovation Spur the Gale of Creative Destruction?” NBER Working Paper No. W7851. Gans, Joshua S. and Stern, Scott (2003a), “The Product Market and the Market for “Ideas”: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs,” Research Policy, 32, 333-350. Gans, Joshua S. and Stern, Scott (2003b), “The Impact of Uncertain IP Rights on the Market for Ideas: Evidence from Patent Grant Delays,” mimeo, Northwestern University. 7

Gilson, Ronald J.(1999),"The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not to Compete, New York University Law Review, 74, 575-629 Grossman, Sanford and Hart, Oliver(1986),"The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration, " Journal of political Economy, 94, 691 719 Hart, Oliver(1995), Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure(Oxford University Press New York, NY) Hellmann, Thomas(2002),"When Do Employees Become Entrepreneurs? "Research Paper No. 1770, Stanford Business School Kim, J and Marschke, G.(2001),Labor Mobility of Scientists, Technological Diffusion, and the Firms Patenting Decision named available at http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstractid=288580 Lessig, Lawrence(2001), The Future of Ideas(Random House, New York) Majewski, Suzanne E and Williamson, Dean V(2003), Incomplete Contracting and the Structure ofR&D Agreements, " mimeo, Harvard University Mazzoleni, Roberto and Nelson, Richard R (1998), "The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: A Contribution to the Current Debate, Research Policy, 27, 273 Merges, Robert P(1995),"Intellectual Property and the Costs of Commercial Exchange A Review Essay, Michigan Law Review, 93, 1570-1615 Merges, Robert P.(1999),"The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions, 13 Harvard Journal of law Technology, 13, 1-54 Merges, Robert P (2000),"Property Rights as Contractual Safeguards, mimeo, UC Berkeley Merges, Robert P, Menell, Peter S. and Lemley, Mark(2003), Intellectual Property in the New Technology Age(3 ed, Aspen Law and Business, New York) Oxley, Joanne E.(1997),"Appropriability Hazards and Governance in Strate Alliances: A Transaction Cost Approach, 13 Journal of Law, Economics Organization 387-409 Oxley, Joanne E(1999),Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-firm Alliances, Journal of Economic Behavior Organization, 38, 283-309 Sampson, Rachelle C(2004),The Cost of Misaligned Governance in R&D Alliances forthcoming in Journal of Law, Economics Organization Teece, David (1986),"Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy, Research Policy, 15, 285- Teece, David(1988),Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm, "in Dosi, Get al.(eds ) Technical Change and Economic Theory 256-281(Frances Pinter, Williamson, Oliver(1975), Markets and Hierarchies(free Press, New York, NY) Williamson, Oliver(1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism(Free Press, New York, NY) 8

Gilson, Ronald J. (1999), “The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial Districts: Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not to Compete,” New York University Law Review, 74, 575-629. Grossman, Sanford and Hart, Oliver (1986), “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691- 719. Hart, Oliver (1995), Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure (Oxford University Press, New York, NY). Hellmann, Thomas (2002), “When Do Employees Become Entrepreneurs?” Research Paper No. 1770, Stanford Business School. Kim, J. and Marschke, G. (2001), “Labor Mobility of Scientists, Technological Diffusion, and the Firm’s Patenting Decision,” mimeo, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=288580. Lessig, Lawrence (2001), The Future of Ideas (Random House, New York). Majewski, Suzanne E. and Williamson, Dean V. (2003), “Incomplete Contracting and the Structure of R&D Agreements,” mimeo, Harvard University. Mazzoleni, Roberto and Nelson, Richard R. (1998), “The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protection: A Contribution to the Current Debate,” Research Policy, 27, 273- 284. Merges, Robert P. (1995), “Intellectual Property and the Costs of Commercial Exchange: A Review Essay,” Michigan Law Review, 93, 1570-1615. Merges, Robert P. (1999), “The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions,” 13 Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, 13, 1-54. Merges, Robert P. (2000), “Property Rights as Contractual Safeguards,” mimeo, UC Berkeley. Merges, Robert P., Menell, Peter S. and Lemley, Mark (2003), Intellectual Property in the New Technology Age (3rd ed., Aspen Law and Business, New York). Oxley, Joanne E. (1997), “Appropriability Hazards and Governance in Strategic Alliances: A Transaction Cost Approach,” 13 Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 387-409. Oxley, Joanne E. (1999), “Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance: The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-firm Alliances,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38, 283-309. Sampson, Rachelle C. (2004), “The Cost of Misaligned Governance in R&D Alliances,” forthcoming in Journal of Law, Economics & Organization. Teece, David (1986), “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy,” Research Policy, 15, 285- 305. Teece, David (1988), “Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm,” in Dosi, G. et al. (eds.), Technical Change and Economic Theory 256-281 (Frances Pinter, London, UK). Williamson, Oliver (1975), Markets and Hierarchies (Free Press, New York, NY). Williamson, Oliver (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (Free Press, New York, NY). 8

点击下载完整版文档(PDF)VIP每日下载上限内不扣除下载券和下载次数;
按次数下载不扣除下载券;
24小时内重复下载只扣除一次;
顺序:VIP每日次数-->可用次数-->下载券;
共11页,试读已结束,阅读完整版请下载
相关文档

关于我们|帮助中心|下载说明|相关软件|意见反馈|联系我们

Copyright © 2008-现在 cucdc.com 高等教育资讯网 版权所有