当前位置:高等教育资讯网  >  中国高校课件下载中心  >  大学文库  >  浏览文档

《法学资料大全》(英文版)知识产权法中的一致性问题

资源类别:文库,文档格式:PDF,文档页数:63,文件大小:356.67KB,团购合买
The law grants patents to inventors and copyrights to authors to encourage investments in technological and cultural innovation. While addressing an appropriability problem faced by innovators, these intellectual property rights create a different problem by supplying rightsholders with powerful weapons
点击下载完整版文档(PDF)

VILlANoVA Public law and legal Theory working Paper series U One For All: The Problem of Uniformity Cost in Intellectual Property law Michael w. carroll Villanova University School of Law Public law and legal theory Working Paper 2005-17 can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collectionathttp:/ssrn.com/abstract=820308

VILLANOVA Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper Series One For All: The Problem of Uniformity Cost in Intellectual Property Law by Michael W. Carroll Villanova University School of Law Public Law and Legal Theory Working Paper 2005-17 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=820308

Vol # THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST ONE FOR ALL: THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST IN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW MICHAEL W CARROLL . INTRODUCTION IL. THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST B. The Problem of Uniformity Cost 5678 A Standard Economic Justification for Intellectual Property Rights. .6 1. The Problem 2. Uniformity Cost Typology 3. Qualifying the Problem II. UNIFORMITY AND ITS LIMITS IN U.S. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 15 A. Uniformity and Institutional Options for Reducing Its Costs.. 15 B. The Constitutional Framework C. Patent law 1. Uniform Entitlements 2. Tailored Entitlements D Copyright Law 1. Uniform Entitlements 2. Tailored Entitlements 39 E Sui Generis Rights F Su 45 IV OPTIONS AND STANDARDS AS TOOLS TO REDUCE UNIFORMITY COSTS 45 A Real Options 45 I Patent 2. Copyright Opti B. Standards in Intellectual Property Entitlements 1. Patent 2. Copyright Associate Professor of Law, Villanova University School of Law. I am grateful to Dan Burk, Brett Frischmann, and Mark Lemley for helpful comments and to the participants in the Third Annual Intellectual Property Scholars'Conference held at Boalt Hall and at the Penn-Wharton-Temple Colloquium who commented on a prior version of this Article. William Freiberg and Edward Topolewski provided superb research assistance. all errors remain mine

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 1 ONE FOR ALL: THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST IN INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW MICHAEL W. CARROLL* I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 II. THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 A. Standard Economic Justification for Intellectual Property Rights . . 6 B. The Problem of Uniformity Cost . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 1. The Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 2. Uniformity Cost Typology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 3. Qualifying the Problem. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 III. UNIFORMITY AND ITS LIMITS IN U.S. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 15 A. Uniformity and Institutional Options for Reducing Its Costs. . . . . 15 B. The Constitutional Framework. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 C. Patent Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 1. Uniform Entitlements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 2. Tailored Entitlements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 D. Copyright Law . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 1. Uniform Entitlements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 2. Tailored Entitlements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39 E. Sui Generis Rights. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 F. Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 IV. OPTIONS AND STANDARDS AS TOOLS TO REDUCE UNIFORMITY COSTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 A. Real Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45 1. Patent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46 2. Copyright . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 3. Scope Options . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 B. Standards in Intellectual Property Entitlements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 1. Patent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56 2. Copyright . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60 * Associate Professor of Law, Villanova University School of Law. I am grateful to Dan Burk, Brett Frischmann, and Mark Lemley for helpful comments and to the participants in the Third Annual Intellectual Property Scholars= Conference held at Boalt Hall and at the Penn-Wharton-Temple Colloquium who commented on a prior version of this Article. William Freiberg and Edward Topolewski provided superb research assistance. All errors remain mine

Vol ## THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST V CONCLUSION 62 . INTRODUCTION The law grants patents to inventors and copyrights to authors to encourage investments in technological and cultural innovation. While addressing an appropriability problem faced by innovators, these intellectual property rights create a different problem by supplying rightsholders with powerful weapons against end-users, direct competitors and follow-on innovators who seek to bring socially beneficial innovations to market. To promote progress, intellectual property law must strike a stifling the efforts of follow-on innovators or the liberties of end-users y balance, providing sufficient incentives for innovation without undi In the law, balance usually calls for context-sensitivity. However intellectual property law protects the owner of each patented invention c copyrighted work of authorship with a largely uniform set of exclusive rights. Historically, this uniformity may have been justified in light of the relative homogeneity of market conditions obtaining with respect to protected subject matter, such as books or mechanical inventions Technological progress since the founding has led to considerable growth in the range of inventions and expressive works to which patent and copyright law apply, respectively. In the modern context, it is clear that innovators' needs for intellectual property protection vary substantially across industries and among types of innovation. Applying a socially costly, uniform solution to problems of differing magnitudes means that There are exceptions and qualifications to the claim that patent and copyright owners enjoy uniform rights, respectively. Nonetheless, as the discussion in Section Ill infra demonstrates, in the main the law does not differentiate the scope or duration of rights granted on the basis of subject matter, level of investment, or any other metric. For purposes of this Article, discussion of"intellectual property"is limited to patent and copyright law. Trademark, trade secret, rights of publicity and other rights in information present related but different features that require separate analysis beyond the scope of this article See, e.g., Dan L. Burk Mark A. Lemley, Is Patent Law Technology Specific,, 17 BERKELEY TECH. LJ. 1155, 1159(2002)[hereinafter Burk Lemley, Technology- Specific?("The useful arts envisioned by the Framers were mechanical inventions useful in a primarily agrarian economy. ) Copyright regulated the publishing business See The Copyright Act of 1790 extended protection only to "maps, charts, and books Copyright Act of 1790, I Stat. 124; see also infra notes XX and accompanying text (charting expansion of copyrightable subject matter) e,e.g. Dan L. Burk Mark A Lemley, Policy Levers in Patent Law, 89 VAL REV 1575, 1581(2003)[hereinafter Burk Lemley, Policy Levers]("[T]he cost of R&D varies widely from industry to industry and from innovation to innovation.

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 2 V. CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 I. INTRODUCTION The law grants patents to inventors and copyrights to authors to encourage investments in technological and cultural innovation. While addressing an appropriability problem faced by innovators, these intellectual property rights create a different problem by supplying rightsholders with powerful weapons against end-users, direct competitors and follow-on innovators who seek to bring socially beneficial innovations to market. To promote progress, intellectual property law must strike a balance, providing sufficient incentives for innovation without unduly stifling the efforts of follow-on innovators or the liberties of end-users. In the law, balance usually calls for context-sensitivity. However, intellectual property law protects the owner of each patented invention or copyrighted work of authorship with a largely uniform set of exclusive rights.1 Historically, this uniformity may have been justified in light of the relative homogeneity of market conditions obtaining with respect to protected subject matter, such as books or mechanical inventions. Technological progress since the founding has led to considerable growth in the range of inventions and expressive works to which patent and copyright law apply, respectively.2 In the modern context, it is clear that innovators’ needs for intellectual property protection vary substantially across industries and among types of innovation.3 Applying a socially costly, uniform solution to problems of differing magnitudes means that 1 There are exceptions and qualifications to the claim that patent and copyright owners enjoy uniform rights, respectively. Nonetheless, as the discussion in Section III infra demonstrates, in the main the law does not differentiate the scope or duration of rights granted on the basis of subject matter, level of investment, or any other metric. For purposes of this Article, discussion of “intellectual property” is limited to patent and copyright law. Trademark, trade secret, rights of publicity and other rights in information present related but different features that require separate analysis beyond the scope of this Article. 2 See, e.g., Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, Is Patent Law Technology Specific?, 17 BERKELEY TECH. L.J. 1155, 1159 (2002) [hereinafter Burk & Lemley, Technology￾Specific?] (AThe >useful arts= envisioned by the Framers were mechanical inventions useful in a primarily agrarian economy.@). Copyright regulated the publishing business. See The Copyright Act of 1790 extended protection only to Amaps, charts, and books@ Copyright Act of 1790, 1 Stat. 124; see also infra notes XX and accompanying text (charting expansion of copyrightable subject matter). 3 See, e.g. Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, Policy Levers in Patent Law, 89 VA. L. REV. 1575, 1581 (2003) [hereinafter Burk & Lemley, Policy Levers] (A[T]he cost of R&D varies widely from industry to industry and from innovation to innovation.@)

Vol ## THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST the law necessarily imposes uniformity costs by underprotecting those who invest in certain costly innovations and overprotecting those with low innovation costs or access to alternative appropriability mechanisms egal scholars recently have begun analyzing the problem of uniformity cost in patent law. Professor Glynn Lunney, Jr. argues that iformity cost is the key to understanding the economic structure of patent law and that recent doctrinal changes affecting the scope of patents demonstrate the point. Further raising the prominence of the problem Professors Dan Burk and Mark Lemley argue in a series of articles and in a forthcoming book that uniformity costs are particularly high in relation to patent laws application to software and biotechnology and that these costs can be reduced by differential application of the Patent Act.' Building on this prior work, this Article includes copyright law within its scope and argues more generally that the problem of uniformity cost is the central problem for intellectual property policymaking. This uniformity-cost perspective is dynamic, accepting that exclusive rights must promise some potential power over price to induce innovation but that different innovator different kinds of promises from the law. From the uniformity-cost perspective, if intellectual property rights were the only policy tool available to promote innovation, perfectly tailored rights that promise innovators only the expected value required to induce socially desirable innovation would be heoretically optimal Intellectual property law falls short of this ideal for a host of reasons including uncertainty about innovation, information asymmetries between policymakers and innovators, administrative costs of tailoring and the political economy of intellectual property policymaking. While substantial, these obstacles do not disable all potential context-sensitivity See generally Glynn S. Lunney, Jr, Patent Law, the Federal Circuit, and the Supreme Court: A Quiet Revolution, 11 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. I(2004)[hereinafter Lunney, Quiet Revolution (discussing uniformity costs). Professor Lunney's colleague Professor Christopher Cotropia has further extended this line of analysis. See Christopher Cotropia, After- Arising" Technologies and Tailoring Patent Scope, 61 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM L (forthcoming 2005): Christopher Cotropia, Patent Claim Interpretation and Information Costs, 9 LEWIS CLARK L REV. 57(2005); Chrisopher Cotropia, " Arising Under"Jurisdiction and Uniformity in Patent Law, 9 MICH TELECOMM. TECH L REV 53 (2003), reprinted at 36 INTELL. PROP. L REV. 209(2004) See DAN L. BURK MARK A LEMLEY, TAILORING INNOVATION LAW(forthcoming 2005); Dan L. Burk Mark A Lemley, Biotechnology's Uncertainty Principle, 54 CASE w.RES L REV. 691(2004): Burk Lemley, Policy Levers, supra note XX; Burk Lemley, Technology-Specific?, supra note XX 6 See infra notes XX and accompanying text(qualifying claim concerning optimality general and optimality of tailored rights in particular)

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 3 the law necessarily imposes uniformity costs by underprotecting those who invest in certain costly innovations and overprotecting those with low innovation costs or access to alternative appropriability mechanisms. Legal scholars recently have begun analyzing the problem of uniformity cost in patent law. Professor Glynn Lunney, Jr. argues that uniformity cost is the key to understanding the economic structure of patent law and that recent doctrinal changes affecting the scope of patents demonstrate the point.4 Further raising the prominence of the problem, Professors Dan Burk and Mark Lemley argue in a series of articles and in a forthcoming book that uniformity costs are particularly high in relation to patent law’s application to software and biotechnology and that these costs can be reduced by differential application of the Patent Act.5 Building on this prior work, this Article includes copyright law within its scope and argues more generally that the problem of uniformity cost is the central problem for intellectual property policymaking. This uniformity-cost perspective is dynamic, accepting that exclusive rights must promise some potential power over price to induce innovation but also recognizing that different innovators require different kinds of promises from the law. From the uniformity-cost perspective, if intellectual property rights were the only policy tool available to promote innovation, perfectly tailored rights that promise innovators only the expected value required to induce socially desirable innovation would be theoretically optimal.6 Intellectual property law falls short of this ideal for a host of reasons including uncertainty about innovation, information asymmetries between policymakers and innovators, administrative costs of tailoring, and the political economy of intellectual property policymaking. While substantial, these obstacles do not disable all potential context-sensitivity 4 See generally Glynn S. Lunney, Jr., Patent Law, the Federal Circuit, and the Supreme Court: A Quiet Revolution, 11 SUP. CT. ECON. REV. 1 (2004) [hereinafter Lunney, Quiet Revolution] (discussing uniformity costs). Professor Lunney’s colleague Professor Christopher Cotropia has further extended this line of analysis. See Christopher Cotropia, “After-Arising” Technologies and Tailoring Patent Scope, 61 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. ___ (forthcoming 2005); Christopher Cotropia, Patent Claim Interpretation and Information Costs, 9 LEWIS & CLARK L. REV. 57 (2005); Chrisopher Cotropia, "Arising Under" Jurisdiction and Uniformity in Patent Law, 9 MICH. TELECOMM. TECH. L. REV. 253 (2003), reprinted at 36 INTELL. PROP. L. REV. 209 (2004). 5 See DAN L. BURK & MARK A. LEMLEY, TAILORING INNOVATION LAW (forthcoming 2005); Dan L. Burk & Mark A. Lemley, Biotechnology’s Uncertainty Principle, 54 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 691 (2004); Burk & Lemley, Policy Levers, supra note XX; Burk & Lemley, Technology- Specific?, supra note XX. 6 See infra notes XX and accompanying text (qualifying claim concerning optimality in general and optimality of tailored rights in particular)

Vol # THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST in intellectual property law. As uniformity costs rise with the growing economic importance of, and variation among, information-centric industries, policymakers should strive harder to maximize context- sensitivity in intellectual property law This Article analyzes current U.S. patent and copyright law from the uniformity-cost perspective and identifies three features that function or should function, to reduce uniformity cost: (1)real options that regulate who acquires, and who keeps, intellectual property rights; (2) flexible standards that define rights to promote context-sensitive application of the law; and(3)legislative or judicial measures that explicitly vary the subject matter,scope, or duration of intellectual property rights. After identifying these this article focuses analysis on the economic function of real options and flexible standards in patent and copyright law. I take up analysis of tailoring intellectual property rights in a separate paper. By making uniformity cost the focus of economic analysis of intellectual property law and by analyzing the features of entitlement design that can be deployed to reduce uniformity cost, this Article supplies a general framework for analyzing the economic stakes in a range of policy debates in contemporary intellectual property law. Moreover, this Article argues for legal realism in the analysis of the formally unifor rights that patent law and copyright law grant and shows that the law is less uniform in practice than some analysts assume This Article unfolds as follows. Section II introduces the uniformity-cost perspective by showing how granting differently-situated innovators a uniform set of rights leads to overprotection in some cases and underprotection in others. Section Ill offers a working definition of uniformity" for purposes of this discussion and through that lens provides a snapshot of current U.S. intellectual property law as specified by constitutional, international, and statutory sources. This Section demonstrates that rights in patent and copyright law generally are uniform but have been tailored for a number of purposes. Section IV demonstrates that in addition to explicitly tailored rights, real options and legal standards are features of current law designed to reduce uniformity This analysis suggests that future research should focus on use these features to reduce uniformity cost. Section V concludes 7 See Michael W. Carroll, Tailoring Intellectual Property Rights(draft April 2005)(on file with author)

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 4 in intellectual property law. As uniformity costs rise with the growing economic importance of, and variation among, information-centric industries, policymakers should strive harder to maximize context￾sensitivity in intellectual property law. This Article analyzes current U.S. patent and copyright law from the uniformity-cost perspective and identifies three features that function, or should function, to reduce uniformity cost: (1) real options that regulate who acquires, and who keeps, intellectual property rights; (2) flexible standards that define rights to promote context-sensitive application of the law; and (3) legislative or judicial measures that explicitly vary the subject matter, scope, or duration of intellectual property rights. After identifying these, this Article focuses analysis on the economic function of real options and flexible standards in patent and copyright law. I take up analysis of tailoring intellectual property rights in a separate paper.7 By making uniformity cost the focus of economic analysis of intellectual property law and by analyzing the features of entitlement design that can be deployed to reduce uniformity cost, this Article supplies a general framework for analyzing the economic stakes in a range of policy debates in contemporary intellectual property law. Moreover, this Article argues for legal realism in the analysis of the formally uniform rights that patent law and copyright law grant and shows that the law is far less uniform in practice than some analysts assume. This Article unfolds as follows. Section II introduces the uniformity-cost perspective by showing how granting differently-situated innovators a uniform set of rights leads to overprotection in some cases and underprotection in others. Section III offers a working definition of “uniformity” for purposes of this discussion and through that lens provides a snapshot of current U.S. intellectual property law as specified by constitutional, international, and statutory sources. This Section demonstrates that rights in patent and copyright law generally are uniform but have been tailored for a number of purposes. Section IV demonstrates that in addition to explicitly tailored rights, real options and legal standards are features of current law designed to reduce uniformity cost. This analysis suggests that future research should focus on how to better use these features to reduce uniformity cost. Section V concludes. 7 See Michael W. Carroll, Tailoring Intellectual Property Rights (draft April 2005) (on file with author)

Vol ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST IL. THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST Economic analysts have long recognized that intellectual property rights impose social costs because they interfere with competitive distribution of information goods. But from a dynamic perspective, some distortion must be tolerated as the price to be paid for having information good created in the first place. The social costs that matter, then, are not all static deadweight losses, but only the distortions caused by rights that are more or less robust than necessary to have induced investments in innovation that deliver a net benefit to society. Uniform intellectual property rights necessarily impose such costs. Therefore, Uniform propert policymaking must manage. This section demonstrates this point by revisiting the standard economic justification for intellectual property ights and then by reorienting this analysis around the problem of formity cost This reorientation reveals that the theoretically optimal policy, if intellectual property rights are the only feasible response to derproduction of valuable information, is to fashion perfectly tailored ights rather than to promote perfect price discrimination, as some theorists suggest. While perfect tailoring is just as elusive as perfect price discrimination, the uniformity-cost perspective shows that the focus of policy analysis should be on how intellectual property rights can be rendered more context-sensitive. Further. this theoretical reorientation emphasizes the role of"law"in the law-and-economics of intellectual property because even after economic analysis identifies industries or technologies for which uniformity costs are particularly high, legal scholars must assess whether legal institutions can competently address this problem. Legal analysis demonstrates that while tailoring rights ex ante is an important strategy for reducing uniformity cost, it is not the only one. As is discussed in Section IV, infra, real options and flexible standards also can be used to inject context sensitivity into the application of formally uniform rights 8 See, e.g, WILLIAM M. LANDES RICHARD A POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 74, 310(2003)(discussing social costs of copyright and patent law, respectively) See id See id. at 40(discussing perfect price discrimination)

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 5 II. THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST Economic analysts have long recognized that intellectual property rights impose social costs because they interfere with competitive distribution of information goods.8 But from a dynamic perspective, some distortion must be tolerated as the price to be paid for having the information good created in the first place.9 The social costs that matter, then, are not all static deadweight losses, but only the distortions caused by rights that are more or less robust than necessary to have induced investments in innovation that deliver a net benefit to society. Uniform intellectual property rights necessarily impose such costs. Therefore, uniformity cost is the central problem that intellectual property policymaking must manage. This section demonstrates this point by revisiting the standard economic justification for intellectual property rights and then by reorienting this analysis around the problem of uniformity cost. This reorientation reveals that the theoretically optimal policy, if intellectual property rights are the only feasible response to underproduction of valuable information, is to fashion perfectly tailored rights rather than to promote perfect price discrimination, as some theorists suggest.10 While perfect tailoring is just as elusive as perfect price discrimination, the uniformity-cost perspective shows that the focus of policy analysis should be on how intellectual property rights can be rendered more context-sensitive. Further, this theoretical reorientation emphasizes the role of “law” in the law-and-economics of intellectual property because even after economic analysis identifies industries or technologies for which uniformity costs are particularly high, legal scholars must assess whether legal institutions can competently address this problem. Legal analysis demonstrates that while tailoring rights ex ante is an important strategy for reducing uniformity cost, it is not the only one. As is discussed in Section IV, infra, real options and flexible standards also can be used to inject context sensitivity into the application of formally uniform rights. 8 See, e.g., WILLIAM M. LANDES & RICHARD A. POSNER, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW 74, 310 (2003) (discussing social costs of copyright and patent law, respectively). 9 See id. 10 See id. at 40 (discussing perfect price discrimination)

Vol # THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST A. Standard Economic Justification for Intellectual Property Rights Intellectual property rights are a second-best solution to an appropriability problem. The now-familiar utilitarian justification for ntellectual property law starts with Thomas Jefferson's observation that Informations is that no one possesses the less, because every other possesses the whole of it... [ H]e who lites his taper at mine. receives light without darkening me. For Jefferson. the capacity for information to"freely spread from one to another over the globe"is part of nature's "benevolent["design. For the economist however, the "benevolent"design of information poses a problem. To the extent that pecuniary motivation drives innovation, we should not expect to see useful information 4 produced unless the producer can recoup his or her investment. Because the distribution of valuable information cannot be controlled in the ways that distribution of scarce goods like tubes of toothpaste or radial tires might be- that is, information can be consumed nonrivalrously -the producer, acting alone, cannot rely on competitive markets to supply a sufficient return to make the investment in producing such information worthwhile. The government Letter from Thomas Jefferson to Isaac McPherson(Aug. 13, 1813), in 6 THE WRITINGS OF THOMAS JEFFERSON 180(HA. Washington, ed. 1861) s Information exhibits public goods characteristics. a public good can be consumed without depletion (non-rivalrous consumption) and can be withheld from nonpaying beneficiaries only at prohibitive cost (non-excludability ) See RoBert COoTER THOMAS ULEN, LAW AND ECONOMICS 40-41(2d ed. 1997); see also wilfried Ver eecl Public Goods: An Ideal Concept, 28 J OF SOCIO-ECONOMICS 139(1999). Information imperfectly excludable but it is because it is its non-rivalrous quality that makes it problematic The terms"valuable" anduseful" information in this article refer to information that is costly to produce and that members of our society find to be useful, informative enriching, or otherwise of value. Such information includes the ideas and expressions or embodiments of those ideas found in, for example, novels, movies, music, methods for manufacturing useful articles(medicines, computers, clothing, etc. ) computer software S Eg, Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property, 75 TEX. L REv. 989, 994(1997)[hereinafter Lemley, Economics of Improvement]("In a private market economy, individuals will not invest in invention or creation... unless they can reasonably expect to make a profit from the endeavor. ") Christian Koboldt Intellectual Property and Optimal Copyright Protection, 19 J OF CULTURAL ECON. 131 134(1995)(same) See, e.g, CARL SHAPIRo HAL VARIAN, INFORMATION RULES: A STRATEGIC GUIDE TO THE NETWORK ECONOMY 3(1999), F M. SChERER DAvID ROSs, INDUSTRIAL

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 6 A. Standard Economic Justification for Intellectual Property Rights Intellectual property rights are a second-best solution to an “appropriability problem.” The now-familiar utilitarian justification for intellectual property law starts with Thomas Jefferson=s observation that information=s Apeculiar character . . . is that no one possesses the less, because every other possesses the whole of it. . . . . [H]e who lites his taper at mine, receives light without darkening me.@ 11 For Jefferson, the capacity for information to Afreely spread from one to another over the globe@ is part of nature=s Abenevolent[]@ design.12 For the economist, however, the Abenevolent@ design of information poses a problem.13 To the extent that pecuniary motivation drives innovation, we should not expect to see useful information14 produced unless the producer can recoup his or her investment.15 Because the distribution of valuable information cannot be controlled in the ways that distribution of scarce goods like tubes of toothpaste or radial tires might be B that is, information can be consumed nonrivalrously B the producer, acting alone, cannot rely on competitive markets to supply a sufficient return to make the investment in producing such information worthwhile.16 The government 11 Letter from Thomas Jefferson to Isaac McPherson (Aug. 13, 1813), in 6 THE WRITINGS OF THOMAS JEFFERSON 180 (H.A. Washington, ed. 1861). 12 Id. 13 Information exhibits public goods characteristics. A public good can be consumed without depletion (non-rivalrous consumption) and can be withheld from nonpaying beneficiaries only at prohibitive cost (non-excludability). See ROBERT COOTER & THOMAS ULEN, LAW AND ECONOMICS 40-41 (2d ed. 1997); see also Wilfried Ver Eecke, Public Goods: An Ideal Concept, 28 J. OF SOCIO-ECONOMICS 139 (1999). Information is imperfectly excludable but it is because it is its non-rivalrous quality that makes it “problematic.” 14 The terms Avaluable@ and Auseful@ information in this Article refer to information that is costly to produce and that members of our society find to be useful, informative, enriching, or otherwise of value. Such information includes the ideas and expressions or embodiments of those ideas found in, for example, novels, movies, music, methods for manufacturing useful articles (medicines, computers, clothing, etc.), computer software, etc. 15 E.g., Mark A. Lemley, The Economics of Improvement in Intellectual Property, 75 TEX. L. REV. 989, 994 (1997) [hereinafter Lemley, Economics of Improvement] (AIn a private market economy, individuals will not invest in invention or creation . . . unless they can reasonably expect to make a profit from the endeavor.@); Christian Koboldt, Intellectual Property and Optimal Copyright Protection, 19 J. OF CULTURAL ECON. 131, 134 (1995) (same). 16 See, e.g., CARL SHAPIRO & HAL VARIAN, INFORMATION RULES: A STRATEGIC GUIDE TO THE NETWORK ECONOMY 3 (1999); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL

Vol # THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST response has been to grant and administer rights under patent and copyright law. Such rights give the innovator the r to exclude or inhibit direct competition, which yields potential power over price. If demand is sufficient, the innovator can use that power to earn a positive return on investments in innovation While addressing underproduction, intellectual property rights also impose social costs. Professor Lemley nicely summarizes these as follows First, intellectual property rights distort markets away from the competitive norm, and therefore create static inefficiencies in the form of deadweight losses. Second intellectual property rights interfere with the ability of other creators to work, and therefore create dynar inefficiencies. Third, the prospect of intellectual property rights encourages rent-seeking behavior that is socially wasteful. Fourth, enforcement of intellectual property right research and development is itself distortionary > Stment in imposes administrative costs. Finally, overinve B The problem of Uniformity Cost Economic analysts generally agree that these social costs must be minimized, and intellectual property rights should be no more robust than necessary to induce the desired level of investment in cultural and technological innovation. However, in both the economic and the law- MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 622(3d ed 1990); See, e.g, Mark tellectual Property, and Fr 054-55(2005)[hereinafter Lemley, Free Riding lan E Novos Michael Waldman The Effects of Increased Copyright Protection: An Analytic Approach, 92 J. POL. ECON 236,237(1984) Lemley, Free Riding, supra note XX, at 1058-59 See, e.g., Lunney, Quiet Revolution, supra note XX, at 5(arguing that patent protection should be provided only to the precise extent necessary to secure each individual innovations ex ante profitability and acknowledging that this level will have to account for unsuccessful research efforts); William W. Fisher Ill, Property and Contract on the Internet, 73 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1203, 1249(1998)(arguing that the goal of copyright law is to give creators enough entitlements to induce them to produce the works from which we all benefit but no more"). The canonical version of this argument was voiced by lord Macauley, who argued that a grant of copyright was a grant of an evil monopoly and that [for the sake of the good we must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is necessary for the purpose of securing the good. Thomas Babington, Lord Macaulay, A Speech Delivered in the house of Commons on the 5th of February, 1841

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 7 response has been to grant and administer rights under patent and copyright law. Such rights give the innovator the power to exclude or inhibit direct competition, which yields potential power over price. If demand is sufficient, the innovator can use that power to earn a positive return on investments in innovation. While addressing underproduction, intellectual property rights also impose social costs. Professor Lemley nicely summarizes these as follows: First, intellectual property rights distort markets away from the competitive norm, and therefore create static inefficiencies in the form of deadweight losses. Second, intellectual property rights interfere with the ability of other creators to work, and therefore create dynamic inefficiencies. Third, the prospect of intellectual property rights encourages rent-seeking behavior that is socially wasteful. Fourth, enforcement of intellectual property rights imposes administrative costs. Finally, overinvestment in research and development is itself distortionary.17 B. The Problem of Uniformity Cost Economic analysts generally agree that these social costs must be minimized, and intellectual property rights should be no more robust than necessary to induce the desired level of investment in cultural and technological innovation.18 However, in both the economic and the law- MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 622 (3d ed. 1990); See, e.g., Mark A. Lemley, Property, Intellectual Property, and Free Riding, 83 TEX. L. REV. 1031, 1054-55 (2005) [hereinafter Lemley, Free Riding]; Ian E. Novos & Michael Waldman, The Effects of Increased Copyright Protection: An Analytic Approach, 92 J. POL. ECON. 236, 237 (1984). 17 Lemley, Free Riding, supra note XX, at 1058-59. 18 See, e.g., Lunney, Quiet Revolution, supra note XX, at 5 (arguing that patent protection should be provided only to the precise extent necessary to secure each individual innovation’s ex ante profitability and acknowledging that this level will have to account for unsuccessful research efforts); William W. Fisher III, Property and Contract on the Internet, 73 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 1203, 1249 (1998) (arguing that the goal of copyright law “is to give creators enough entitlements to induce them to produce the works from which we all benefit but no more”). The canonical version of this argument was voiced by Lord Macauley, who argued that a grant of copyright was a grant of an evil monopoly and that “[f]or the sake of the good we must submit to the evil; but the evil ought not to last a day longer than is necessary for the purpose of securing the good.” Thomas Babington, Lord Macaulay, A Speech Delivered in the House of Commons on the 5th of February, 1841

Vol ## THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST and-economics literature, the problem of social cost in intellectual property law often is discussed at a very high level of abstraction. The literature surrounding the optimal length of a patent is a typical example Neoclassical economic models concerning an optimal patent term often hold that optimality is conditional, implicitly recognizing that efficiency might dictate varying terms from patent to patent. Other analysts make the point more explicitly. But these economists offer no suggestion for how variable patent terms might be implemented, and those who contemplate the matter find the administrative difficulties intractable These economists apparently have recognized and despaired over, the problem of uniformity cost in intellectual property law. This despair is premature. Economic analysis can help identify situations in which uniformity costs are particularly high, but it will require pragmatic legal analysis to identify ways in which the legal system can competentI redress the problem 1. The Problem Legal scholars only recently have begun to analyze the social costs or uniform rights as a general problem in intellectual property law Analyzing U.S. patent law, Professor Lunney has advanced a formal economic model of uniformity cost that assesses the trade-offs between strictly uniform rights, rights tailored to individual innovations, an certain intermediate options. At bottom he shows"[e]ven where an innovative product represents the most valuable use of available resources in Speeches by Lord Macaulay with his Minute on Indian Education 156, 162(G M Professor John Duffy argues that the mobility of capital makes analysis causal connection between rights and investment levels unstable. See John F Intellectual Property Isolationism And The Average Cost Thesis, 83 TEX. L. REV 1078-89(2005). But, Professor Lemley rightly responds that because intellectual property rights distort the market away from competitive equilibrium, entry will not necessarily compete away supracompetitive returns. See Lemley, What is Different, supra note Xx at 1102-03 i9 See infra notes XX and accompanying text( discussing economic literature on patent See infra notes XX and accompanying text(discussing recognition of uniformity cost in the literature) 2I See Lunney, Quiet Revolution, supra note XX, at 6(stating that uniformity costs rise as gap between optimal uniform level of protection and level needed for individual innovation increases) 2 See Lunney, Quiet Revolution,, supra note XX, SIV

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 8 and-economics literature, the problem of social cost in intellectual property law often is discussed at a very high level of abstraction. The literature surrounding the optimal length of a patent is a typical example. Neoclassical economic models concerning an optimal patent term often hold that optimality is conditional, implicitly recognizing that efficiency might dictate varying terms from patent to patent.19 Other analysts make the point more explicitly.20 But these economists offer no suggestion for how variable patent terms might be implemented, and those who contemplate the matter find the administrative difficulties intractable. These economists apparently have recognized and despaired over, the problem of uniformity cost in intellectual property law.21 This despair is premature. Economic analysis can help identify situations in which uniformity costs are particularly high, but it will require pragmatic legal analysis to identify ways in which the legal system can competently redress the problem. 1. The Problem Legal scholars only recently have begun to analyze the social costs of uniform rights as a general problem in intellectual property law. Analyzing U.S. patent law, Professor Lunney has advanced a formal economic model of uniformity cost that assesses the trade-offs between strictly uniform rights, rights tailored to individual innovations, and certain intermediate options.22 At bottom he shows “[e]ven where an innovative product represents the most valuable use of available resources in Speeches by Lord Macaulay with his Minute on Indian Education 156, 162 (G.M. Young ed., 1935). Professor John Duffy argues that the mobility of capital makes analysis of the causal connection between rights and investment levels unstable. See John F. Duffy, Intellectual Property Isolationism And The Average Cost Thesis, 83 TEX. L. REV. 1077, 1078-89 (2005). But, Professor Lemley rightly responds that because intellectual property rights distort the market away from competitive equilibrium, entry will not necessarily compete away supracompetitive returns. See Lemley, What is Different, supra note XX, at 1102-03. 19 See infra notes XX and accompanying text (discussing economic literature on patent length). 20 See infra notes XX and accompanying text (discussing recognition of uniformity cost in the literature). 21 See Lunney, Quiet Revolution,, supra note XX, at 6 (stating that uniformity costs rise as gap between optimal uniform level of protection and level needed for individual innovation increases). 22 See Lunney, Quiet Revolution,, supra note XX, § IV

Vol ## THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST an optimal uniform scheme of protection will provide protection that will leave some desirable innovative products unprofitable To illustrate the point, imagine four innovations, A, B, C, and D These could be musical compositions, types of business software biotechnological inventions, or chemical compounds with pharmacological uses. Society places a value of 50 on each of these if it is available for use and is free from any intellectual property rights. Assume that intellectual property rights apply uniformly to all covered forms of information and can be calibrated to yield levels of protection ranging from 0 to 3. Innovations B-D will require a level of protection above to be created and distributed. so that a alone will be created and distributed at 0. A and b will be created and distributed at level 1. and so on. as protection increases, however, social value decreases because some users are priced out of desired uses for which they would pay more than marginal cost. Assume that each increase in the level of protection reduces the social value of each innovation by 10. Sliding the protection lever upward yields the following distribution of social values Table 1 Level of Protection Innovations Created Total Social Value and Distributed B A,B.C A,B,C,D a policymaker interested in maximizing social value from intellectual property rights but bound by the uniformity condition would set the level of protection at 2, leaving innovation D unprofitable even though society places a net positive value of 20 on having it created. Within this highly stylized example, it is easy to see that if the uniformity condition could be relaxed, it would be possible to adjust rights to entice the creation of A-D by, for example, eliminating protection for A and reducing the scope or duration of rights granted to B See lunney, Quiet Revolution,, supra note XX, at 50-51 Some empirical data suggests that innovations such as A are more than hypothetical Edwin Mansfield interviewed research and development managers from 100 randomly selected firms to ask what percentage of the firms inventions would have been developed and brought to market in the absence of patent protection. See Edwin Mansfield, Patents and Innovation: An Empirical Study, 32 MGMT SCIENCE 173(1986)

Vol. ##] THE PROBLEM OF UNIFORMITY COST 9 . . . . an optimal uniform scheme of protection will provide protection that will leave some desirable innovative products unprofitable.” 23 To illustrate the point, imagine four innovations, A, B, C, and D. These could be musical compositions, types of business software, biotechnological inventions, or chemical compounds with pharmacological uses. Society places a value of 50 on each of these if it is available for use and is free from any intellectual property rights. Assume that intellectual property rights apply uniformly to all covered forms of information and can be calibrated to yield levels of protection ranging from 0 to 3. Innovations B-D will require a level of protection above 0 to be created and distributed, so that A alone will be created and distributed at 0, A and B will be created and distributed at level 1, and so on. As protection increases, however, social value decreases because some users are priced out of desired uses for which they would pay more than marginal cost. Assume that each increase in the level of protection reduces the social value of each innovation by 10. Sliding the protection lever upward yields the following distribution of social values: Table 1 Level of Protection Innovations Created and Distributed Total Social Value 0 A 50 1 A, B 80 2 A,B,C 90 3 A,B,C,D 80 A policymaker interested in maximizing social value from intellectual property rights but bound by the uniformity condition would set the level of protection at 2, leaving innovation D unprofitable even though society places a net positive value of 20 on having it created. Within this highly stylized example, it is easy to see that if the uniformity condition could be relaxed, it would be possible to adjust rights to entice the creation of A-D by, for example, eliminating protection for A and reducing the scope or duration of rights granted to B.24 23 See Lunney, Quiet Revolution,, supra note XX, at 50-51. 24 Some empirical data suggests that innovations such as A are more than hypothetical. Edwin Mansfield interviewed research and development managers from 100 randomly￾selected firms to ask what percentage of the firm’s inventions would have been developed and brought to market in the absence of patent protection. See Edwin Mansfield, Patents and Innovation: An Empirical Study, 32 MGMT SCIENCE 173 (1986)

点击下载完整版文档(PDF)VIP每日下载上限内不扣除下载券和下载次数;
按次数下载不扣除下载券;
24小时内重复下载只扣除一次;
顺序:VIP每日次数-->可用次数-->下载券;
共63页,可试读20页,点击继续阅读 ↓↓
相关文档

关于我们|帮助中心|下载说明|相关软件|意见反馈|联系我们

Copyright © 2008-现在 cucdc.com 高等教育资讯网 版权所有