International Organization http://journals.cambridge.orq/INO Additional services for International Organization: Email alerts:Click here Subscriptions:Click here Commercial reprints:Click here Terms of use:Click here World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre-World War I Europe David M.Rowe International Organization Volume 53/Issue 02/March 1999,pp 195-231 DOI:10.1162/002081899550869,Published online:12 August 2003 Link to this article:http://journals.cambridge.org/ abstract S0020818399440688 How to cite this article: David M.Rowe(1999).World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre-World War I Europe.International Organization,53,pp 195-231 doi:10.1162/002081899550869 Request Permissions:Click here CMi JOURNALS Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/INO,IP address:211.80.95.69 on 14 Jan 2015
International Organization http://journals.cambridge.org/INO Additional services for International Organization: Email alerts: Click here Subscriptions: Click here Commercial reprints: Click here Terms of use : Click here World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre–World War I Europe David M. Rowe International Organization / Volume 53 / Issue 02 / March 1999, pp 195 - 231 DOI: 10.1162/002081899550869, Published online: 12 August 2003 Link to this article: http://journals.cambridge.org/ abstract_S0020818399440688 How to cite this article: David M. Rowe (1999). World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre–World War I Europe. International Organization, 53, pp 195-231 doi:10.1162/002081899550869 Request Permissions : Click here Downloaded from http://journals.cambridge.org/INO, IP address: 211.80.95.69 on 14 Jan 2015
World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre-World War I Europe David M.Rowe Profound and rapid changes in the costs and risks of international trade are now widely acknowledged to be a potent source of domestic political conflict.By altering the relative prices of goods available from world markets,these changes alter the rewards that flow to different factors of production from different economic activi- ties.These distributional consequences of changing levels of trade,in turn,alter the configuration of interests in the domestic political economy,strain existing political alignments,and enable the construction of new political coalitions.Thus,global changes in the economy,such as the transportation and telecommunications revolu- tions in the nineteenth and mid-twentieth centuries or the collapse of international trade and finance during the interwar years,will have global consequences as they reverberate within and through the domestic politics of all countries that trade on world markets.! But surely such changes do more than influence countries'domestic politics.As scholars of international relations recognize,these changes occur within a system of sovereign states where concerns over national security are important determinants of state behavior.Consequently,should we not expect these changes to also systemati- cally and predictably affect the economic constraints within which states must formu- late and pursue their security interests?And,by affecting these constraints,to affect the broader stability of international relations? I thank David Bearce,Pamela Camerra-Rowe,Thomas Christensen,Albert Fishlow,Timothy Frye, John Garofano,Peter Gourevitch,Peter Katzenstein,Jonathan Kirshner,Judy Kullberg,David Lake,Ned Lebow,Edward Mansfield,Patrick McDonald,Joseph McGarvey,Patrick Morgan,James Morrow,Wayne Sandholtz Randall Schweller,David Skidmore,Andrew Sobel,Katherine Lawyer Sperling.Alec Stone Sweet,the participants in seminars at the Global Peace and Conflict Studies program of the University of California,Irvine,and the Peace Studies Program of Cornell University,and the anonymous reviewers for comments on previous drafts.I alone am responsible for any errors.I also thank Kenyon College for the gracious use of its library resources while I was an affiliated scholar at that institution.This research was supported by the National Science Foundation.grant no.SBR-9709556. 1.See Gourevitch 1978 and 1986;Rogowski 1987 and 1989:Frieden 1991:Keohane and Milner 1996: and Alt et al.1996. International Organization 53.2,Spring 1999,pp.195-231 1999 by The IO Foundation and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology
World Economic Expansion and National Security in Pre–World War I Europe David M. Rowe Profound and rapid changes in the costs and risks of international trade are now widely acknowledged to be a potentsource of domestic political con ict. By altering the relative prices of goods available from world markets, these changes alter the rewards that ow to different factors of production from different economic activities. These distributional consequences of changing levels of trade, in turn, alter the con guration of interests in the domestic political economy, strain existing political alignments, and enable the construction of new political coalitions. Thus, global changes in the economy, such as the transportation and telecommunicationsrevolutions in the nineteenth and mid-twentieth centuries or the collapse of international trade and nance during the interwar years, will have global consequences as they reverberate within and through the domestic politics of all countries that trade on world markets.1 But surely such changes do more than in uence countries’ domestic politics. As scholars of international relationsrecognize, these changes occur within a system of sovereign states where concerns over nationalsecurity are important determinants of state behavior. Consequently,should we not expect these changes to also systematically and predictably affect the economic constraintswithin which states must formulate and pursue their security interests? And, by affecting these constraints, to affect the broader stability of international relations? I thank David Bearce, Pamela Camerra-Rowe, Thomas Christensen, Albert Fishlow, Timothy Frye, John Garofano, Peter Gourevitch, Peter Katzenstein, Jonathan Kirshner, Judy Kullberg, David Lake, Ned Lebow, Edward Mans eld, Patrick McDonald,Joseph McGarvey, Patrick Morgan,James Morrow,Wayne Sandholtz, Randall Schweller, David Skidmore, Andrew Sobel, Katherine Lawyer Sperling, Alec Stone Sweet, the participants in seminars at the Global Peace and Con ict Studies program of the University of California, Irvine, and the Peace Studies Program of Cornell University, and the anonymousreviewers for comments on previous drafts. I alone am responsible for any errors. I also thank Kenyon College for the gracious use of its library resources while I was an affiliated scholar at that institution.This research was supported by the National Science Foundation, grant no. SBR–9709556. 1. See Gourevitch 1978 and 1986; Rogowski 1987 and 1989; Frieden 1991; Keohane and Milner 1996; and Alt et al. 1996. International Organization 53, 2, Spring 1999, pp. 195–231 r 1999 by The IO Foundation and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology
196 International Organization I build on the fundamental insights of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem from inter- national economics to argue that exogenous changes in the costs and risks of interna- tional economic exchange can powerfully affect the economic constraints that under- lie the security behavior of states and that these effects will vary predictably across states with different factor endowments.2 As preliminary evidence,I submit that the theory accords surprisingly well with the experiences of the European great powers in the rapidly expanding world economy prior to World War I and that many of the factors that contributed most to the breakdown of international relations in 1914 follow directly from the changing pattern of economic constraints that the theory predicts.By raising the economic returns that flowed to those resources most critical to military power in Europe prior to World War I,especially labor,the expansion of world trade progressively constrained the abilities of the European powers to mobi- lize these resources for security purposes.The growing difficulties of mobilizing resources raised international tensions and undermined stability by fueling anxieties in each state that it was declining relative to its rivals,which,in turn,generated powerful,systemwide incentives to go to war before one's own position became untenable.The rapid expansion of the world economy thus unleashed its own di- lemma for pre-World War I Europe,for the more Europe prospered from the deepen- ing integration of world markets,the more fragile became the security foundations on which that prosperity ultimately rested. Clearly,the relationship between the international economy and the security poli- tics of states has generated a substantial literature in international relations,from debates between liberals and realists over the consequences of economic interdepen- dence to the economic dynamics underlying internationalhegemony and the rise and fall of great powers.I seek to contribute to this literature in at least four ways.First, by extending a widely accepted theory about the economic consequences of interna- tional trade-the Stolper-Samuelson theorem-to the realm of security,I seek to specify more precisely the causal mechanisms by which a changing world economy affects a state's security.Second,by focusing on the domestic distributional conse- quences of internationaleconomic exchange,I depart from the widespread belief that trade influences security primarily through its effects on aggregate national income (rising levels of trade increase a state's military potential by raising national income; falling levels of trade lower it).This departure enables me to make important and counterintuitive propositions.Contrary to conventional wisdom,I argue that the ex- pansion of trade can impair the military power of some states even as it makes them more prosperous.Third,I offer a new interpretation of the origins of World War I that traces many of its causes to the expansion of the world economy.Finally,by showing how world economic expansion undermined European security,I directly challenge the conventional wisdom that the expansion of trade necessarily and unambiguously enhances the prospects for international peace. I must also stress,however,that my argument is preliminary and that my empirical evidence only demonstrates its plausibility.Nor do I imply that changing economic 2.See Stolper and Samuelson 1941/42;and Rogowski 1987 and 1989
I build on the fundamental insights of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem from international economicsto argue that exogenous changesin the costs and risks of international economic exchange can powerfully affect the economic constraintsthat underlie the security behavior of states and that these effects will vary predictably across states with different factor endowments.2 As preliminary evidence, I submit that the theory accords surprisingly well with the experiences of the European great powers in the rapidly expanding world economy prior to World War I and that many of the factors that contributed most to the breakdown of international relations in 1914 follow directly from the changing pattern of economic constraints that the theory predicts. By raising the economic returns that owed to those resources most critical to military power in Europe prior to World War I, especially labor, the expansion of world trade progressively constrained the abilities of the European powers to mobilize these resources for security purposes. The growing difficulties of mobilizing resources raised international tensions and undermined stability by fueling anxieties in each state that it was declining relative to its rivals, which, in turn, generated powerful, systemwide incentives to go to war before one’s own position became untenable. The rapid expansion of the world economy thus unleashed its own dilemma for pre–World War I Europe, for the more Europe prospered from the deepening integration of world markets, the more fragile became the security foundations on which that prosperity ultimately rested. Clearly, the relationship between the international economy and the security politics of states has generated a substantial literature in international relations, from debates between liberals and realists over the consequences of economic interdependence to the economic dynamics underlying internationalhegemony and the rise and fall of great powers. I seek to contribute to this literature in at least four ways. First, by extending a widely accepted theory about the economic consequences of international trade—the Stolper-Samuelson theorem—to the realm of security, I seek to specify more precisely the causal mechanisms by which a changing world economy affects a state’s security. Second, by focusing on the domestic distributional consequences of international economic exchange,I depart from the widespread beliefthat trade in uences security primarily through its effects on aggregate national income (rising levels of trade increase a state’s military potential by raising national income; falling levels of trade lower it). This departure enables me to make important and counterintuitive propositions. Contrary to conventional wisdom, I argue that the expansion of trade can impair the military power of some states even as it makes them more prosperous.Third, I offer a new interpretation of the origins of World War I that traces many of its causes to the expansion of the world economy. Finally, by showing how world economic expansion undermined European security, I directly challenge the conventional wisdom that the expansion of trade necessarily and unambiguously enhancesthe prospects for international peace. I must also stress, however, that my argument is preliminary and that my empirical evidence only demonstrates its plausibility. Nor do I imply that changing economic 2. See Stolper and Samuelson 1941/42; and Rogowski 1987 and 1989. 196 International Organization
Economic Expansion and Security in Pre-WWI Europe 197 constraints are the only,or even the most important,factor in determining the secu- rity politics of states or that I offer a general explanation of international security and conflict.Yet the ability of this theory to link important empirical and theoretical issues-ranging from the growing fragility of the European state system prior to World War I,to the impact of trade on international stability,to the dynamics of hegemonic theory-suggests that it taps a rich vein of inquiry of central relevance to scholars of international affairs. The Economics of Security and Changing National Exposure to the International Economy All states confront a significant economic problem.Security is costly.To build mili- tary establishments capable of defending vital national interests,states must draw resources out of the national economy and employ them in the security sector.3 For example,industrial capital is necessary to build warships,tanks,and aircraft;human capital is necessary to develop new military technologies and the doctrines that gov- ern the use of military force;labor is necessary for troops.This economic aspect of security implies that states may be vulnerable to externally induced changes in the costs and risks of international exchange.Because these changes alter the relative prices of domestic economic resources,they also alter the cost of using these re- sources for security purposes.In this way,a changing world economy may fundamen- tally shape the economic constraints on a state's security policies. To explore this idea,I develop a simple framework that builds on the Stolper- Samuelson theorem from international trade theory.This theorem holds that increas- ing exposure of the national economy to international trade benefits the owners and intensive users of those resources in which the economy is abundantly endowed relative to the rest of the world,while harming the owners and intensive users of those resources in which the economy is poorly endowed.For example,in an economy abundant in labor but scarce in capital,increasing exposure to international trade benefits labor and harms capital.Decreasing exposure to the international economy reverses these effects,so that owners and users of the economy's abundant resources suffer,while the owners and users of the economy's scarce resources gain. I link these domestic consequences of a changing world economy to changes in the underlying economic constraints on a state's security behavior by making two assump- tions.I assume,first,that the state's difficulty in mobilizing specific resources for security purposes will be directly related to the returns that those resources earn elsewhere in the national economy.The more that resources eamn in nonsecurity sectors of the national economy,the more difficult it becomes for the state to use them for security.This assumption follows directly from the fact that scarcity is 3.Tily1990. 4.Although built on assumptions that almost never hold,the theorem's central insight appears robust. See Corden 1974,93-104;Leamer 1984;Ethier 1984;and Rogowski 1989,16-20
constraints are the only, or even the most important, factor in determining the security politics of states or that I offer a general explanation of internationalsecurity and con ict. Yet the ability of this theory to link important empirical and theoretical issues—ranging from the growing fragility of the European state system prior to World War I, to the impact of trade on international stability, to the dynamics of hegemonic theory—suggests that it taps a rich vein of inquiry of central relevance to scholars of international affairs. The Economics of Security and Changing National Exposure to the International Economy All states confront a signi cant economic problem. Security is costly. To build military establishments capable of defending vital national interests, states must draw resources out of the national economy and employ them in the security sector.3 For example, industrial capital is necessary to build warships, tanks, and aircraft; human capital is necessary to develop new military technologies and the doctrinesthat govern the use of military force; labor is necessary for troops. This economic aspect of security implies that states may be vulnerable to externally induced changes in the costs and risks of international exchange. Because these changes alter the relative prices of domestic economic resources, they also alter the cost of using these resources for security purposes.In this way, a changingworld economy may fundamentally shape the economic constraints on a state’s security policies. To explore this idea, I develop a simple framework that builds on the StolperSamuelson theorem from internationaltrade theory.4 Thistheorem holdsthat increasing exposure of the national economy to international trade bene ts the owners and intensive users of those resources in which the economy is abundantly endowed relative to the rest of the world, while harming the owners and intensive users of those resourcesin which the economy is poorly endowed. For example, in an economy abundant in labor but scarce in capital, increasing exposure to international trade bene ts labor and harms capital. Decreasing exposure to the international economy reverses these effects, so that owners and users of the economy’s abundantresources suffer, while the owners and users of the economy’s scarce resources gain. I link these domestic consequences of a changingworld economy to changesin the underlying economic constraints on a state’ssecurity behavior by making two assumptions. I assume, rst, that the state’s difficulty in mobilizing speci c resources for security purposes will be directly related to the returns that those resources earn elsewhere in the national economy. The more that resources earn in nonsecurity sectors of the national economy, the more difficult it becomes for the state to use them for security. This assumption follows directly from the fact that scarcity is 3. Tilly 1990. 4. Although built on assumptions that almost never hold, the theorem’s central insight appears robust. See Corden 1974, 93–104; Leamer 1984; Ethier 1984; and Rogowski 1989, 16–20. Economic Expansion and Security in Pre–WWI Europe 197
198 International Organization ubiquitous in economic life,forcing the state to compete with other actors for the use of economic resources.Thus,as the number of potential claimants to a particular resource grows (that is,the higher the demand for that resource),the more difficult becomes the state's task of procuring it for security purposes. How these difficulties become manifested in a state's security politics will be determined by the institutions and practices used to mobilize resources from the national economy.Where the state simply pays for the use of a resource,these diffi- culties will be reflected in the military budget.To prevent resources from being bid away to other users,the state must pay higher prices for resources in high demand (and thus enjoy fewer budgetary degrees of freedom)than for resources in low de- mand.Should its compensation fail to keep pace with the demand for resources elsewhere in the economy,the state will experience either shortages in the quantity or deficiencies in the quality of those resources it procures.Where the state compels the supply of resources (conscription,for example),the holders of those resources will invest greater efforts in evading state directives,the greater the potential returns from employing those resources in alternative uses.5 In this instance,the state's difficulties will manifest themselves not as budgetary pressures,but more subtly,such as through resource holders evading or shirking military duties,raising demands for better com- pensation or,in the extreme,engaging in political resistance.6 Second,I assume that not all resources contribute equally to military power.Con- sequently,the state's ability to respond to changing relative prices by effortlessly substituting toward resources whose prices are falling will be limited by the extent to which these less costly resources are militarily useful.I make this assumption for three reasons.First,existing military technologies may not permit substituting cheaper resources for dearer ones.Prior to World War I,mechanized forms of transportation could not replace muscle power as the critical means of battlefield mobility.This reality both necessitated the use of large field armies to concentrate force against the enemy and limited the degree to which European militaries could make their armies more "weapons(that is,capital)intensive."As William McNeil notes,"an army that sought to achieve mobility in the field,as all European armies did before 1914. simply lacked the transport capacity to supply more than a token population of guns that spat forth bullets at the rate of 600 a minute."7 Second,the state's ability to substitute among various resources is often limited by exogenous strategic circum- stances.Pre-World War I Britain,for example,required a(capital-intensive)navy to protect its empire and home islands.This strategic necessity prevented it from respond- ing to a rise in the relative price of capital by using more intensively those resources 5.These effects will be mitigated where the state directly holds the particular resource.Even here it seems plausible that the state's use of the resource is more likely to be contested,either by factions within the state or by social elites who would capture the returns from alternative uses,the greater the potential returns of those uses. 6.The translation of shifting opportunity costs of compulsory military service into political activity is straightforward.The more the opportunity costs of military service rise,the more likely are resource holders to demand policies that offset them. 7.McNeil 1982,273.See also Storz 1992,295-97
ubiquitousin economic life, forcing the state to compete with other actors for the use of economic resources. Thus, as the number of potential claimants to a particular resource grows (that is, the higher the demand for that resource), the more difficult becomes the state’s task of procuring it for security purposes. How these difficulties become manifested in a state’s security politics will be determined by the institutions and practices used to mobilize resources from the national economy. Where the state simply pays for the use of a resource, these difficulties will be re ected in the military budget. To prevent resources from being bid away to other users, the state must pay higher prices for resources in high demand (and thus enjoy fewer budgetary degrees of freedom) than for resources in low demand. Should its compensation fail to keep pace with the demand for resources elsewhere in the economy, the state will experience eithershortagesin the quantity or de cienciesin the quality of those resources it procures. Where the state compels the supply of resources (conscription, for example), the holders of those resources will invest greater efforts in evading state directives, the greater the potentialreturns from employing those resources in alternative uses.5 In thisinstance, the state’s difficulties will manifest themselves not as budgetary pressures, but more subtly,such as through resource holders evading or shirking military duties, raising demands for better compensation or, in the extreme, engaging in politicalresistance.6 Second, I assume that not all resources contribute equally to military power. Consequently, the state’s ability to respond to changing relative prices by effortlessly substituting toward resources whose prices are falling will be limited by the extent to which these less costly resources are militarily useful. I make this assumption for three reasons. First, existingmilitary technologiesmay not permitsubstitutingcheaper resources for dearer ones. Prior to World War I, mechanized forms of transportation could not replace muscle power as the critical means of battle eld mobility. This reality both necessitated the use of large eld armies to concentrate force against the enemy and limited the degree to which European militaries could make their armies more ‘‘weapons(that is, capital) intensive.’’As William McNeil notes, ‘‘an army that sought to achieve mobility in the eld, as all European armies did before 1914, simply lacked the transport capacity to supply more than a token population of guns that spat forth bullets at the rate of 600 a minute.’’ 7 Second, the state’s ability to substitute among various resources is often limited by exogenous strategic circumstances. Pre–World War I Britain, for example, required a (capital-intensive) navy to protect its empire and home islands.Thisstrategic necessity prevented it from responding to a rise in the relative price of capital by using more intensively those resources 5. These effects will be mitigated where the state directly holds the particular resource. Even here it seems plausible that the state’s use of the resource is more likely to be contested, either by factions within the state or by social elites who would capture the returns from alternative uses, the greater the potential returns of those uses. 6. The translation of shifting opportunity costs of compulsory military service into political activity is straightforward. The more the opportunity costs of military service rise, the more likely are resource holders to demand policies that offset them. 7. McNeil 1982, 273. See also Storz 1992, 295–97. 198 International Organization
Economic Expansion and Security in Pre-WWI Europe 199 National exposure to the international economy Rising Falling State's difficulty mobilizing locally abundant resources Increases Decreases State's difficulty mobilizing locally Decreases Increases scarce resources FIGURE 1.Predicted changes in the difficulty of mobilizing locally abundant and locally scarce resources (in this case,land)that were becoming less expensive under the impact of trade.s Third,slow turnover in the officer corps combined with the fact that militaries are only infrequently tested in war often impede change,allowing obsolete weapons and outmoded operational concepts to linger.9 These two assumptions,when combined with the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, yield two sets of propositions about the ways in which changing national exposure to the internationaleconomy affects the economic constraints on a state's security.First, increasing exposure to the international economy will increase the state's difficulty of mobilizing resources in which the economy is abundantly endowed while decreas- ing the difficulty of mobilizing resources in which it is scarce.Declining exposure reverses these effects(see Figure 1).Second,increasing exposure to the international economy will cause states in which militarily relevant resources are locally abundant to experience a general tightening of economic constraints on their security,states in which these resources are locally scarce to experience a general relaxing of eco- nomic constraints,and states in which some militarily relevant resources are locally abundant but others locally scarce to experience a mixed movement of constraints. For this last group,the overall consequences of growing exposure to the international economy will be determined by the extent to which they can substitute locally scarce resources for those that are locally abundant.Again,declining exposure reverses these effects(see Figure 2). Preliminary Evidence:European Security Prior to World War I To probe the plausibility of my theory,I explore how well it captures the experiences of the five European great powers-Austria-Hungary,Britain,France,Germany,and 8.This second point also suggests that trade can affect the security interests of similarly endowed economies differently.depending on exogenous strategic circumstances.I thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting these points. 9.Rosen 1991
(in this case, land) that were becoming less expensive under the impact of trade.8 Third, slow turnover in the officer corps combined with the fact that militaries are only infrequently tested in war often impede change, allowing obsolete weapons and outmoded operational conceptsto linger.9 These two assumptions, when combined with the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, yield two sets of propositions about the ways in which changing national exposure to the international economy affects the economic constraints on a state’s security. First, increasing exposure to the international economy will increase the state’s difficulty of mobilizing resources in which the economy is abundantlyendowed while decreasing the difficulty of mobilizing resources in which it is scarce. Declining exposure reverses these effects (see Figure 1). Second, increasing exposure to the international economy will cause statesin which militarily relevant resources are locally abundant to experience a general tightening of economic constraints on their security,states in which these resources are locally scarce to experience a general relaxing of economic constraints, and states in which some militarily relevant resources are locally abundant but others locally scarce to experience a mixed movement of constraints. For thislast group, the overall consequences of growing exposure to the international economy will be determined by the extent to which they can substitute locally scarce resources for those that are locally abundant. Again, declining exposure reverses these effects (see Figure 2). Preliminary Evidence: European Security Prior to World War I To probe the plausibility of my theory, I explore how well it capturesthe experiences of the ve European great powers—Austria-Hungary, Britain, France, Germany, and 8. This second point also suggests that trade can affect the security interests of similarly endowed economies differently, depending on exogenous strategic circumstances. I thank an anonymous reviewer for suggesting these points. 9. Rosen 1991. FIGURE 1. Predicted changes in the diffõculty of mobilizing locally abundant and locally scarce resources Economic Expansion and Security in Pre–WWI Europe 199
200 International Organization National exposure to the international economy Falling Rising Militarily relevant resources are Tightening of Relaxing of locally abundant economic economic constraints on constraints on the state's the state's security security Some militarily relevant resources Mixed Mixed are locally abundant,others are movement of movement of locally scarce constraints constraints Overall Overall movement of movement of constraints constraints determined by determined by the extent to the extent to which state can which state can substitute substitute locally scarce locally for locally abundant for abundant locally scarce resources resources Militarily relevant resources are Relaxing of Tightening of locally scarce economic economic constraints on constraints on the state's the state's security security FIGURE 2.Predicted changes in economic constraints on the state's security Russia-in the decades prior to World War I.During this period,technological revo- lutions in communications and transportation,combined with international political stability,significantly lowered the costs and risks associated with international ex- change and led to a dramatic and sustained expansion of the volume and range of goods,services,and capital being exchanged on world markets.Between 1870 and 1900,world trade almost doubled,and in the remaining years before World War I it
Russia—in the decades prior to World War I. During this period, technologicalrevolutions in communications and transportation, combined with international political stability, signi cantly lowered the costs and risks associated with international exchange and led to a dramatic and sustained expansion of the volume and range of goods, services, and capital being exchanged on world markets. Between 1870 and 1900, world trade almost doubled, and in the remaining years before World War I it FIGURE 2. Predicted changes in economic constraints on the state’s security 200 International Organization
Economic Expansion and Security in Pre-WWI Europe 201 Abundant in labor Land poor Land rich Capital locally abundant Britain,France, Germany None Capital locally scarce Austria-Hungary Russia Source:Rogowski 1989. FIGURE 3.Economic endowments of the European great powers grew by nearly half again.10 This expansion of trade led to the growing exposure of regional and national markets to the world economy-a development that pro- foundly affected almost every aspect of European economic,social,and political life. To generate specific predictions about this development for the security politics of the European great powers requires a model of the economy and knowledge about the importance and substitutability of various resources in European military compe- tition.To address the first issue,I follow Ronald Rogowski's study on the effects of trade on domestic political alignments and classify each power according to its rela- tive endowment in a three-factor model of land,labor,and capital,yielding a pattern in which the European powers occupied three niches in the world economy.2 Britain, France,and Germany were abundant in labor and capital but scarce in land relative to the rest of the world;Russia was abundant in labor and land but scarce in capital;and Austria-Hungary was abundant in labor but scarce in land and capital(see Figure 3).3 Second,each of these economic factors differed in its importance to military com- petition in Europe.Land was the least valuable factor and,except for the peasantry (the intensive users of this resource)as a source of military labor,contributed little to the military strength of a great power.4 More important were capital and labor,al- though the relative weight of each varied as to whether the issue was one of naval or land warfare.Key to naval competition was the state's ability to muster the eco- nomy's industrial capacity to build heavier,faster,and ever more technologically 10.Rogowski 1989,21. 11.Gourevitch 1986,chap.3. 12.Rogowski 1989.Modeling always involves a tradeoff between parsimony and accuracy.I believe the advantages provided by a three-factor model-parsimony.simplicity,and tractability-outweigh any potential loss in accuracy.Midford seeks to improve the accuracy of Rogowski's work by using a more disaggregated model.Midford 1993. 13.Rogowski1989,25-30. 14.Clearly,land and geography matter in military competition.States that possess vast swaths of land can use it as a defensive strategic asset.But given the perceived advantages of offensive warfare in the nineteenth century,land mattered less than either capital or labor,which were key to building and pro- jecting mobile armies
grew by nearly half again.10 This expansion of trade led to the growing exposure of regional and national markets to the world economy—a development that profoundly affected almost every aspect of European economic, social, and political life.11 To generate speci c predictions about this developmentfor the security politics of the European great powers requires a model of the economy and knowledge about the importance and substitutabilityof variousresources in European military competition. To address the rst issue, I follow Ronald Rogowski’s study on the effects of trade on domestic political alignments and classify each power according to its relative endowment in a three-factor model of land, labor, and capital, yielding a pattern in which the European powers occupied three nichesin the world economy.12 Britain, France, and Germany were abundant in labor and capital butscarce in land relative to the rest of the world; Russia was abundant in labor and land butscarce in capital; and Austria-Hungary was abundant in labor butscarce in land and capital(see Figure 3).13 Second, each of these economic factors differed in its importance to military competition in Europe. Land was the least valuable factor and, except for the peasantry (the intensive users of thisresource) as a source of military labor, contributed little to the military strength of a great power.14 More important were capital and labor, although the relative weight of each varied as to whether the issue was one of naval or land warfare. Key to naval competition was the state’s ability to muster the economy’s industrial capacity to build heavier, faster, and ever more technologically 10. Rogowski 1989, 21. 11. Gourevitch 1986, chap. 3. 12. Rogowski 1989. Modeling always involves a tradeoff between parsimony and accuracy. I believe the advantages provided by a three-factor model—parsimony, simplicity, and tractability—outweigh any potential loss in accuracy. Midford seeks to improve the accuracy of Rogowski’s work by using a more disaggregated model. Midford 1993. 13. Rogowski 1989, 25–30. 14. Clearly, land and geography matter in military competition. States that possess vast swaths of land can use it as a defensive strategic asset. But given the perceived advantages of offensive warfare in the nineteenth century, land mattered less than either capital or labor, which were key to building and projecting mobile armies. FIGURE 3. Economic endowments of the European great powers Economic Expansion and Security in Pre–WWI Europe 201
202 International Organization sophisticated warships.15 On land,the individualsoldier was the basic unit of a state's military strength.The standardization and mass production of weaponry meant that individual soldiers could now be outfitted much more cheaply,and increases in the accuracy,range,and firepower of their weapons made them much more lethal,and vulnerable,in combat,thus requiring the use of large forces to absorb combat casual- ties.16 As a consequence,hardware comprised a relatively small component of a state's landward military power before 1914;more important was the sheer number of soldiers a state could field in battle.17 Finally,the substitutability between these factors was limited.Ships,not sailors, were the key ingredient of naval power.Adding extra personnel to a ship once it was fully staffed simply would not increase its war-fighting abilities.On shore,it was muscle,not machines,that mattered most.The ability to substitute capital for labor was sharply limited by the fact that Europe's armies had not yet solved the problem of battlefield mobility. We can now predict that the expanding world economy will generate three pattems of shifting economic constraints on the European great powers(see Figure 4).First, Britain,France,and Germany will confront a general tightening of economic con- straints on their security.Each will experience growing difficulties in mobilizing those resources most critical to military competition-capital and labor-into the military.They will also find the peasantry(the intensive users of land)to be a shrink- ing source of military labor as labor-intensive export sectors attract lower wage labor out of land-intensive agriculture.Second,Austria-Hungary will experience a mixed movement of constraints:increasing difficulties in mobilizing labor but a growing ease in mobilizing capital.It,too,will find the peasantry to be a fleeting source of military labor.Third,Russia will also experience a mixed movement of constraints: increasing difficulties in mobilizing both labor and the peasantry (the holders and intensive users of Russia's other abundant resource-land)into the military and an increasing ability to mobilize capital.s And,although both Austria-Hungary and Russia will experience a growing ease in mobilizing capital for security purposes,the continental geographic positions of these states,the critical importance of land-based armies to their security,and the limited ability to substitute capital for labor in land warfare imply that the net effect of an expanding world economy will be to tighten the economic constraints on the security of these capital-poor states as well. Keeping in mind that these changing constraints will manifest themselves in differ- ent ways under different institutional settings,I submit that these hypotheses capture succinctly the changing political economy of security in pre-World War I Europe.I will consider,first,whether the predicted patterns of shifting constraints are evident in the security politics of the great powers and,second,whether and how these shifting constraints may have affected European security. 15.See McNeil 1982;Sumida 1989;and Stevenson 1996,10,n.15. 16.Posen1993,83-84. 17.See Stevenson 1996,62;and Herrmann 1996,228. 18.By World War I,most of Russia's productive agricultural land was in the hands of the peasantry. Lieven 1983.18
sophisticatedwarships.15 On land, the individualsoldier was the basic unit of a state’s military strength. The standardization and mass production of weaponry meant that individualsoldiers could now be out tted much more cheaply, and increases in the accuracy, range, and repower of their weapons made them much more lethal, and vulnerable, in combat, thus requiring the use of large forces to absorb combat casualties.16 As a consequence, hardware comprised a relatively small component of a state’s landward military power before 1914; more important was the sheer number of soldiers a state could eld in battle.17 Finally, the substitutability between these factors was limited. Ships, not sailors, were the key ingredient of naval power. Adding extra personnel to a ship once it was fully staffed simply would not increase its war- ghting abilities. On shore, it was muscle, not machines, that mattered most. The ability to substitute capital for labor was sharply limited by the fact that Europe’s armies had not yet solved the problem of battle eld mobility. We can now predict that the expandingworld economy will generate three patterns of shifting economic constraints on the European great powers (see Figure 4). First, Britain, France, and Germany will confront a general tightening of economic constraints on their security. Each will experience growing difficulties in mobilizing those resources most critical to military competition—capital and labor—into the military. They will also nd the peasantry (the intensive users of land) to be a shrinking source of military labor as labor-intensive export sectors attract lower wage labor out of land-intensive agriculture. Second, Austria-Hungary will experience a mixed movement of constraints: increasing difficulties in mobilizing labor but a growing ease in mobilizing capital. It, too, will nd the peasantry to be a eeting source of military labor. Third, Russia will also experience a mixed movement of constraints: increasing difficulties in mobilizing both labor and the peasantry (the holders and intensive users of Russia’s other abundant resource—land) into the military and an increasing ability to mobilize capital.18 And, although both Austria-Hungary and Russia will experience a growing ease in mobilizing capitalfor security purposes, the continentalgeographic positions of these states, the critical importance of land-based armies to their security, and the limited ability to substitute capital for labor in land warfare imply that the net effect of an expanding world economy will be to tighten the economic constraints on the security of these capital-poorstates as well. Keeping in mind that these changing constraintswill manifest themselvesin different ways under different institutionalsettings, I submit that these hypotheses capture succinctly the changing political economy of security in pre–World War I Europe. I will consider, rst, whether the predicted patterns of shifting constraints are evident in the security politics of the great powers and, second, whether and how these shifting constraints may have affected European security. 15. See McNeil 1982; Sumida 1989; and Stevenson 1996, 10, n.15. 16. Posen 1993, 83–84. 17. See Stevenson 1996, 62; and Herrmann 1996, 228. 18. By World War I, most of Russia’s productive agricultural land was in the hands of the peasantry. Lieven 1983, 18. 202 International Organization
Economic Expansion and Security in Pre-WWI Europe 203 Abundant in labor Land poor Land rich Capital abundant Britain,France, None Germany General tightening of constraints Increasing difficulty mobilizing labor Increasing difficulty mobilizing capital Reliable peasantry Capital scarce Austria-Hungary Russia Mixed movement of Mixed movement of constraints constraints Increasing difficulty Increasing difficulty mobilizing labor mobilizing labor Decreasing difficulty Decreasing difficulty mobilizing capital mobilizing capital Reliable peasantry Unreliable peasantry FIGURE 4.Predicted changes in economic constraints on the European great powers prior to World War I Britain,France,Germany-Tightening Constraints Ample evidence suggests that Britain,France,and Germany experienced increasing difficulty in mobilizing their locally abundant resources,labor and capital,prior to World War I.I turn first to labor.Unique among the European powers,Britain used voluntary enlistment to recruit military labor.Although Britain doubled the net pay of army recruits in the latter half of the nineteenth century,army wages lagged be- hind civilian wages,causing chronic shortages of recruits.Between 1910and 1913. Britain needed to recruit 34,000 new soldiers each year but managed to attract an 19.See Spiers 1980.54-55;and Skelley 1977.181-218
Britain, France, Germany—Tightening Constraints Ample evidence suggests that Britain, France, and Germany experienced increasing difficulty in mobilizing their locally abundant resources, labor and capital, prior to World War I. I turn rst to labor. Unique among the European powers, Britain used voluntary enlistment to recruit military labor. Although Britain doubled the net pay of army recruits in the latter half of the nineteenth century, army wages lagged behind civilian wages, causing chronic shortages of recruits.19 Between 1910 and 1913, Britain needed to recruit 34,000 new soldiers each year but managed to attract an 19. See Spiers 1980, 54–55; and Skelley 1977, 181–218. FIGURE 4. Predicted changes in economic constraints on the European great powers prior to World War I Economic Expansion and Security in Pre–WWI Europe 203