North American Journal of Ecopomics and Finance 54 (2020)100826 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect North American Journal of Economics and Finance ELSEVIER journal homepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/najef Implied risk aversion and pricing kernel in the FTSE 100 index Wen Ju Liao",Hao-Chang Sung ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT ve the RCH (TGARCH)n stent v "volatility s dislocavyonarepresentai ng at pirical pricing kemel in shape and magnitude. 1.Introduction t's risk a n he in investor's preferences for differ the ch on deriving the pricing k el empi (RND)can bed bility density can be estimate om historical prices of t underlyin ng autho d inrevised form 2 August August201
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect North American Journal of Economics and Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/najef Implied risk aversion and pricing kernel in the FTSE 100 index Wen Ju Liaoa , Hao-Chang Sungb,⁎ aDepartment of Finance, Fujian Business University, 19, Huang Pu, Gulou District, Fuzhou, Fujian, People's Republic of China bDepartment of Finance, College of Economics, Jinan University, No. 601 Huangpu Avenue West, Guanzhou, Guandong 510632, People’s Republic of China ARTICLE INFO Keywords: Pricing kernel Risk aversion Risk neutral density Positive convolution approximation Volatility smile Pricing kernel puzzle JEL: C14 G12 ABSTRACT This paper studies the estimation of the pricing kernel and explains the pricing kernel puzzle found in the FTSE 100 index. We use prices of options and futures on the FTSE 100 index to derive the risk neutral density (RND). The option-implied RND is inverted by using two nonparametric methods: the implied-volatility surface interpolation method and the positive convolution approximation (PCA) method. The actual density distribution is estimated from the historical data of the FTSE 100 index by using the threshold GARCH (TGARCH) model. The results show that the RNDs derived from the two methods above are relatively negatively skewed and fat-tailed, compared to the actual probability density, that is consistent with the phenomenon of “volatility smile.” The derived risk aversion is found to be locally increasing at the center, but decreasing at both tails asymmetrically. This is the so-called pricing kernel puzzle. The simulation results based on a representative agent model with two state variables show that the pricing kernel is locally increasing with the wealth at the level of 1 and is consistent with the empirical pricing kernel in shape and magnitude. 1. Introduction A representative agent’s risk aversion can be inferred from pricing kernel. In asset pricing theory, it has shown that the pricing kernel summarizes the representative investor’s preferences for different states of the world.1 If we can know the pricing kernel, we can then infer the risk attitude of market participants toward unknown future prices. In the literature, early research on deriving the pricing kernel empirically relies on investors’ portfolio holdings or on consumption data. Nevertheless, the conclusions from studies based on the consumption data are inconsistent, particularly regarding the magnitude and characteristics of the relative risk aversion. On the other hand, several studies considering to invert the pricing kernel from actual trading prices of options have established a better underpinning of theory (Jackwerth, 2000; Rosenberg & Engle, 2002). Empirically, pricing kernel can be evaluated by the ratio of risk-neutral probabilities to actual probabilities. The risk-neutral density (RND) can be derived from option prices, and the actual probability density can be estimated from historical prices of the underlying asset. The use of cross-section data of option prices exhibits informative advantage because of the availability of plenty of daily crosssection option prices data.2 Using the option prices data can also help avoid the estimated errors related to the consumption data. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2018.08.009 Received 4 May 2018; Received in revised form 2 August 2018; Accepted 8 August 2018 ⁎ Corresponding author. E-mail address: frrg4125@hotmail.com (H.-C. Sung). 1 Under the no-arbitrage condition, knowing the pricing kernel can help find the true value of an asset, that is, S E = Q ( ) X , where S is the asset price, EQ (·) refers to the expectation under the risk-neutral density Q, is the pricing kernel or discount factor and X is the asset payoffs. Pricing kernel is aggregated with risk preferences of the representative agent in different states. 2Daily and intradaily cross-sectional option prices have specific expiration dates and different strike prices when payoffs are realized, and that futures contracts also have finite-horizon maturity. But, to incorporate the options price data to estimate the RND, we need to impose the arbitragefree assumption on observed option prices. North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 Available online 22 August 2018 1062-9408/ © 2018 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. T
WJ.Liao and H.C.Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020)100826 ()empirical pricin kemel is the preference function that best fitsass payoffs density.With a more nce (e.g p matingt d for a dyna optionson FTSE 10and s&P500 indexesand ignored the pricing kerel by design n,1998)and the ater.This (2015)bocum 00. cally.the onically decreasi zle by est mating both rNd and subiective dels the co To explain the pricing kerel puzzle found in our study on the FTSE 100 index options in the LIFFE(London Inte tility smile RNDn how to extract and risk aversion from actual probability densities and RNDs. 0P0 Section 6 concludes. 2.Pricing kernel and risk aversion nsume at datet and ast s maxE [U(Wr)] (1) s.t.dW:=(rW.W.a:(u-r))dr a:W:adz w≥0.t≤x≤T 0w.Sn卫=r-Uw.s业 (3) where(WS)denotes the indirect utility function for this investor.The terminal condition at date=T is a Gemmill and Shackleton (2005)examine whether ect theory can explain the extraordinary ste ess of the volatility smile in ncial Times Stock Exch TcAd he lenec cfs evident in stock markets
As argued in Rosenberg and Engle (2002), empirical pricing kernel is the preference function that best fits asset prices given forecasted payoffs density. With a more general framework for utility functions admitting risk preference (e.g. prospect theory)3 and estimating the pricing kernel at the sequence of points in time, the pricing kernel can be extended for a dynamic structure. Bliss and Panigirtzoglou (2004) infer the risk aversion from both power-form and exponential-form utility functions and RNDs embedded in cross-sections of options on FTSE 100 and S&P500 indexes4 and ignored the pricing kernel by design. To derive empirical or implied pricing kernel, we need to estimate implied RND and actual probability density for the FTSE 100 index returns at first. To obtain the RND, we use the put options on FTSE 100 index with moneyness ranging from 0.82 to 1.16 Specifically, we compare two nonparametric methods, including the implied-volatility surface fitting method (Derman, 1998) and the PCA method (Bondarenko, 2003b). Regarding the actual probability density, we evaluate it by a Monte Carlo simulation based on the estimation results from the threshold GARCH (TGARCH) model of Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle (1993). 5 The results show that the average empirical pricing kernel implied from the FTSE 100 index options exhibits a tilde-shaped pattern. This is the so-called “pricing kernel puzzle,” and has been documented in Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000), Jackwerth (2000), Rosenberg and Engle (2002), Hill (2013), and Fengler and Hin (2015) based on the study of the S&P 500 index options6 . We also find that the implied risk aversion and relative risk aversion are U-shaped, as found by Jackwerth (2000) and Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000), which is an anomaly that confronts with the economic theory. The pricing kernel puzzle arises from the fact that, theoretically, the pricing kernel should be monotonically decreasing but, empirically, it increases locally for some range of wealth levels. A finding of locally increasing pricing kernel implies that the representative investor is not risk averse. Some studies have undertaken to explain the reason for the pricing kernel puzzle by estimating both RND and subjective probability density at the same time and dealing with demand based models (Ziegler, 2007; Chabi-Yo, Garcia, & Renault, 2008; Christoffersen, Heston, & Jacobs, 2013; Song & Xiu, 2016). However, in these studies, analytical pricing kernels cannot fit well with the corresponding empirical pricing kernel puzzle in shape and magnitude. To explain the pricing kernel puzzle found in our study on the FTSE 100 index options in the LIFFE (London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange), we simulate a price kernel function using Brown and Jackwerth (2012)’s approach. Under the framework of a representative agent model, by specifying volatility as an additional momentum state variable, we can capture the empirical patterns in the pricing kernel, which is consistent with the locally increasing pricing kernel and the volatility smile. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we explain the relation between actual probability density and RND and how to extract pricing kernel and risk aversion from actual probability densities and RNDs. Section 3 documents methods of inverting implied pricing kernels from the data of option prices. Section 4 discusses pricing kernel puzzle and the possible explanations to resolve this puzzle. The empirical results from the FTSE 100 option data are presented and analyzed in Section 5. Section 6 concludes. 2. Pricing kernel and risk aversion We consider a complete market economy, thus, we can derive the stock price by solving the optimization problem of a representative agent (Constantinides, 1982). Suppose, initially at date t, the investor has one share of the stock as endowment, and this investor can only consume at date t and at a future date, T. Between dates t and T, this representative investor considers to invest a fraction ( ) of wealth to the stock at date , t T . At date T, the investor’s wealth becomes WT. Suppose the stock price, St, is a stochastic process, which follows dS µS dt t t = + dZt, where µ and are the mean and volatility of St, respectively, and Z is a standard Brownian motion. Suppose U (·) denotes the investor’s utility function and be twice continuously differentiable, concave, and increasing with wealth. The investor solves for the optimal asset holding at date , , by maximizing the discounted expected utility: max [ ( )] E U W t T (1) s. t. ( dW rW W = + ( )) µ r d + W dZ (2) W t 0, , T where W denotes the investor’s wealth at date , ; t T r is the risk-free interest rate. The first-order condition for the optimization problem above can be rewritten as follows, = J W S W e J W S t W ( , , ) ( , , ) , r t t t ( ) (3) where J W S ( , , ) denotes the indirect utility function for this investor. The terminal condition at date = T is 3Gemmill and Shackleton (2005) examine whether cumulative prospect theory can explain the extraordinary steepness of the volatility smile in the loss domain, which is equivalent to a risk-neutral distribution with a fat left-tail. 4 The FTSE 100 Index is a share index of the 100 largest companies listed on the London Stock Exchange, starting January 3, 1984. FTSE is the abbreviation of Financial Times Stock Exchange. 5 TGARCH model allows for asymmetric relation between volatility and squared past errors, that is the “leverage effect” evident in stock markets. 6 Bliss and Panigirtzoglou (2004) do not find the ”pricing kernel puzzle” evident in their study. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 2
WJ.Liao and H.-C Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54(2020)10082 U'(w)=e-U'(w5 (4) where =即t'(号(号 Under a complete and frictionless market.the theoretical relation between the risk-neutral density (o(Sr)and actual density distribution (P(ST))is established as follows (see Ait-Sahalia Lo,1998:Jackwerth,2000) (6) h久ekno不Onn-bane yeo dae abe obtand by combining the actual probability density,thedaives.With the implied riak averion,w can unde 3.Methods of estimating implied pricing kernels In a co entative in by this invest The prcing mel can be derived from optimizing problems if w 3.1.Option prices and risk-neutral densities Breeden and Litzenberger (1978)show that RND,Q(ST),is related to the European option prices by where s is the c value of the underlvin e,and Tis time remaining before the expiration date. from the group of curve-fitting methods,and the other is the PCA method(Bondarenko,2003b)that belongs to the group of kemel arametric methods avoid to assume any parametric restrictions on either the underlyi t price ocess or on the family of the RNDs belong to.knowedge for the RNDs.Amng the three groupsof Besides.we know that the class of re agent utility funct ns which are implied by the Black and Scholes (1973)model belongs to the 3
U W e U W ( ) T = ( ) , r T t t T ( ) (4) where = µ r dZ µ r exp{ ds 1 2 }. t s t 2 (5) Under a complete and frictionless market, the theoretical relation between the risk-neutral density ( Q S( T) and actual density distribution ( P S( ) T ) is established as follows (see Ait-Sahalia & Lo, 1998; Jackwerth, 2000): = Q S P S e U S U S S ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ). T T r T t T t T T ( ) (6) The function ( ) S T T is the pricing kernel. Thus, if we know P S( ) T and Q S( ) T , we can find out the pricing kernel. If we take the derivative of T with respect to ST, we obtain = e U S U S ( ) ( ) . T r T t T t ( ) (7) In addition, taking the ratio of Eqs. (6) and (7), and multiplying ST, we have exactly the Arrow-Pratt measure of relative riskaversion, A S rt T ( ). S = = = U S U S S A S Q S Q S S P S P S S ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) . T T T T T T rt T T T T T T T Hence, we obtain a computable expression for the implied relative risk aversion. This also yields the implied absolute risk aversion computable from the data (Ait-Sahalia & Lo, 1998; Jackwerth, 2000). Meanwhile, it shows that the value of the relative risk aversion can be obtained by combining the actual probability density, the RND and their first derivatives. With the implied risk aversion, we can understand how the investor’s risk preference varies across the investment horizons.7 3. Methods of estimating implied pricing kernels In a complete-market economy, there exists a representative investor, and a market index, e.g., the FTSE 100 index, can work as a representative of the aggregate wealth held by this investor (see, for example, Lucas, 1978). In a representative-agent economy, equilibrium asset prices reflect the agent’s preferences and beliefs. The pricing kernel can be derived from optimizing problems if we assume concave utility functions. However, the results of empirical pricing kernel derived from macroeconomic consumption data are not consistent with the concavity of utility function. Instead, we can derive the implied pricing kernel or risk aversion by finding the RND the actual probability density at first. Below we introduce the two methods used in this paper to derive the RNDs, including implied-volatility surface fitting method of Derman (1998), hereafter IV method, and the PCA method of Bondarenko (2003b). To obtain the actual probability density for the FTSE 100 index returns, we use the historical returns of FTSE 100 index to estimate a TGARCH model and use its estimated parameters to construct an actual density probability. 3.1. Option prices and risk-neutral densities Breeden and Litzenberger (1978) show that RND, Q S( ) T , is related to the European option prices by = = Q S e C S K T t K ( ) ( , , ) T r T t t K S ( ) 2 2 T, (8) where St is the current value of the underlying asset, K is the option strike price, and T t is time remaining before the expiration date. However, the available option prices do not provide a continuous call price function. Hence, we have to construct a continuous function of option prices by fitting a smoothing function to the available data. According to Jackwerth (2004), instead of picking a few parameters of a parametric risk-neutral probability distribution, a most efficient way is to fit the risk-neutral probability distribution either point-wise or build it up from linear segment (or even from nonlinear pieces or surfaces). In Jackwerth (2004)’s survey, there are three groups of nonparametric methods – maximum entropy, curve-fitting, and kernel methods. In this paper, we compare two nonparametric methods – one is the IV method (Derman, 1998) from the group of curve-fitting methods, and the other is the PCA method (Bondarenko, 2003b) that belongs to the group of kernel methods. The nonparametric methods avoid to assume any parametric restrictions on either the underlying asset price process or on the family of distributions that the RNDs belong to. They neither require any prior knowledge for the RNDs. Among the three groups of 7 Besides, we know that the class of representative agent utility functions which are implied by the Black and Scholes (1973) model belongs to the class of the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA). Hence, using our empirical risk-aversion functions estimated from the FTSE 100 option prices, we can verify if the assumption of CRRA accurately fits the empirical pattern. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 3
WJ.Liao and H.C.Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020)100826 on ethods are designed to find rNDs that fit the ontion data and that e the o infor e es and then use the Breeden icePon)mehods are ofen usd (Se Ait-Sahalia pint for backing out rnDs.Thus wecnevndrto fit thefunctionf ostrike prices Once the impied volatiities are ftted,we can sbyusiogthcimpicdoatitsind den- to ev te th e implied vo 3.1.1.Implied-Volatiliry surface fitting aV)method A most straightforward way to calculate the RNDs numericaly impied voatilities We may interpolate the implied volatility smile by using (Shin 0,1993 exponentially,and estimate the implied-volatility surface as follows m=a+月(T-)+月e鸣r-m oehs益色的p宽dsw where r-t is time to maturity.m.F is the futures price.and K is the exercise atilities are inte nve th ult to e RND.Since the st and highest strike prices.As ested by Shm 3.12.(PCA)method proces(2)it and is stil valid for small samples;(3)it ensures arbitrag-freestmtors()it iscom pecial set of admissible densities from which the optimal density is selected.The optima density is the oe that gives the best fit tothe option fu ns that can be expressed as a we hegin by fixin function.(x)E L4 So ve can re escale)with the bandwidth to construct a new density)such that)=).For a fixed).let the htain the pCA ne th ed o =The Matlab code is available atwww c.uk/ccfea/ g
nonparametric methods, maximum entropy methods are designed to find RNDs that fit the option data and that presume the least information relative to a prior probability distribution. However, as argued in Jackwerth (2004), the main problem with entropy methods is from the use of the logarithm in its objective function. For small values of probability, the logarithm of such small values turns into large negative value. Hence, the maximization procedure will be predominated by those large negative values and yield a misleading result. An improved approach to fitting the RND is to fit a function of option prices across strike prices and then use the BreedenLitzenberger (Breeden & Litzenberger, 1978) result to take the second derivatives of the option price function with respect to strike prices and obtain the RND after appropriate scaling. Within the class of such methods, kernel methods are often used (See, Ait-Sahalia & Lo, 1998, 2000; Perignon & Villa, 2002; Song & Xiu, 2016). In recent literature, curve fitting of the implied volatility has become the most popular starting point for backing out RNDs. Thus, we can even consider to fit the function of implied volatilities across strike prices. Once the implied volatilities are fitted, we can calculate the function of option prices by using the implied volatilities, and then apply Breeden-Litzenberger result to evaluate the RND. Such approach uses curve-fitting methods to fit the implied volatilities. The advantage from such implied-volatility fitting methods lies in that the implied volatilities are much more similar in magnitude across strike prices than across option prices. When the fitted implied-volatilities do not vary rapidly in strike prices, such methods can produce arbitrage-free RND straightforward. Next, we introduce the IV and PCA methods. The IV method is used to find a smoothed implied volatility, and belongs to the group of curve-fitting methods. The PCA approach proposed by Breeden and Litzenberger (1978) aims to construct a flexible admissible set for available densities. This approach belongs to kernel methods. 3.1.1. Implied-Volatility surface fitting (IV) method A most straightforward way to calculate the RNDs would be to interpolate or smoothing the observed option prices directly. However, the curvature of the option pricing formula is difficult to approximate with commonly used methods. Similarly, small fitted price errors will have a large effect on the RNDs, especially in the tails. Generally, prices can be interpolated, but it is more stable numerically to interpolate implied volatilities. We may interpolate the implied volatility smile by using cubic splines (Shimko, 1993; Campa, Chang, & Reider, 1998) or fit the implied volatility surface by using linear interpolation (Derman, 1998). In this study, we fit an implied-volatility surface and use it to derive implied RND.8 We let the surface be linear across moneyness and the slope decreases exponentially, and estimate the implied-volatility surface as follows: = + ( ) T t + e m, IV T t 0 1 2 ( ) 3 where T t is time to maturity, m = , F K F T t log( / )t is the futures price, and K is the exercise price. We use 100 points to produce equally spaced strike prices over the range and then fit the implied volatilities. Fitted implied-volatilities are interpolated into the BlackScholes model9 to derive the option prices that can be expressed as a continuous function of the strike prices. With the function of call option prices, we then use Breeden-Litzenberger result to extract the RND. Since the range of available strike prices is limited, the implied RND distribution will only expand between the lowest and highest strike prices. As suggested by Shimko (1993), we have to fit a lognormal distribution at each tail so that the total distribution can sum up to one. Fitting lognormal distributions at the tails of the implied RND function is equivalent to assuming that the volatility smile is flat outside the range of observations. 3.1.2. Positive convolution approximation (PCA) method Bondarenko (2003b) propose the PCA method and find PCA method outperforms several popular methods.10 PCA is a new nonparametric approach to estimate the RND and exhibits four properties – (1) it is completely agnostic about the data generating process; (2) it controls against overfitting and is still valid for small samples; (3) it ensures arbitrage-free estimators; (4) it is computationally simple.11 The basic idea of PCA is to build up a special set of admissible densities from which the optimal density is selected. The optimal density is the one that gives the best fit to the option prices. The admissible set includes functions that can be expressed as a convolution of a fixed positive kernel and another density. Using PCA approach, we do not need the information about the tail distribution of the asset prices. Moreover, it allows us to get a flexible admissible set for available densities and select an optimal bandwidth to solve for the trade-off between smoothness and fit. Denote Ld as the set of all probability density functions. At first, we begin by fixing a basis density or kernel function, ( ) x Ld. So we can rescale ( ) x with the bandwidth h to construct a new density ( ) x h such that h ( ) ( ) x = h x h 1 . For a fixed ( ) x h , let the approximation set W W h = h be a convolution of h and another density. Wh contains all admissible or candidate densities. And we can search for the optimal density in Wh that best fits the given cross-section option prices. In practice, we obtain the PCA estimator of RND, f , by minimizing the sum of squared pricing errors between observed option prices and theoretical prices. For example, suppose { } Pi denotes a cross-sectional observations of put prices with strike prices 8 The Matlab code is available atwww.essex.ac.uk/ccfea/. 9 Note that this method does not require the Black-Scholes model to be correct. The Black-Scholes model is simply used to transform the data from one space to another. 10 Bondarenko (2003b) compares RNDs derived from the PCA, mixture of log-normals, Hermite polynomials, and sigma-shape polynomials methods and concludes that PCA is a promising alternative to the competitors. 11 The Matlab code for PCA method is available at tigger.uic.edu/ olegb/. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 4
WJ.Liao and H.-C Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54(2020)10082 x<<.<x corresponding to the RND f(x).In this case,we can obtain f by -0-9 where f(x)is the s nstruct the admissible set and the basis daren (10 op hod and easy to impl of the RND.Second,PCA is overfitting and can bear the curse of dif In the pliow 2udnAP Jo sd t n pun 'aop enausaul -ne ty for ret omy to the real- dof inve r the sto deled us sticity (ARCH)model of Engle(19)and generalized autoregressive condi andi, 0)and in depo hwed that the GRCH model ets GARCH model has bee also exploited to for ast VIX and est 时 G and Engle (2002)and Barone-Adesi,Engle,and Mancini (2008)all fit the TGARCH model to historical rns.We estimate para mizing the quasi log likelihood function mption zons of equity index returns such tha they match the ensity ributi ordin tosv GARC efer to 199 aptianofcondt could lead to a slight oversmoothing but remove spurious multimodalities.We have als
x x x 1 2 < < < n corresponding to the RND f x( ) . In this case, we can obtain f by min ( ( )) , P D f x f i i 2 2 Wh (9) where D f x( )i 2 is the second integral of f x( ) . To obtain the PCA estimator, we have to construct the admissible set Wh, and the basis density ( ) x at first. The choice of the bandwidth for constructing the admissible set Wh is essential for the PCA estimator, whereas a specific choice of the basis density ( ) x is less important (Bondarenko, 2003b). For a better choice of kernel function and the optimal bandwidth h0, Bondarenko (2003b) suggests the use of a Gaussian kernel. We also use a discrete version of the admissible set to solve for the PCA optimization equation, i.e., Eq. (11), numerically: = = = = = { | ( ) g L g x a ( ), for 0, 1}. x z a a h z d k k h k k k K k 1 W (10) Let z k z k = form a equally-spaced grid with the grid side z . Here, h W z is a subset of Wh. With a sufficiently small grid size of z, the two sets can be made arbitrary close. The optimal h and z are set as h h = 0.95 0 and z h = 0.5 so that any density g in the continuous set W0 can be approximately close by some density g in the discrete set h W z . PCA method is useful in inverting RND from traded option prices because of two reasons. First, PCA method is straightforward and easy to implement. We only need to choose a base density and the bandwidth to construct the admissible set. PCA method will produce smooth, arbitrage-free estimators of the RND. Second, PCA is constrained from overfitting and can bear the curse of differentiation and the curse of dimensionality. 3.2. Actual probability density distribution In the risk-neutral world, all expected returns are equal to the risk-free rate. Risk-neutral investors would not require a risk premium to bear risks. Therefore, under this situation, prices of derivatives can be inferred without market risk preference. But, the actual probability density or real-world probability density for returns is switched from the risk-neutral economy to the real-world economy. The actual probability density is related to risk factors of the sentiments of investors over the future price uncertainties. Three salient features of equity index return process have been discussed in literature (see Ghysels, Harvey, & Renault, 1996), including (1) return volatility is stochastic and mean-reverting; (2) return volatility responds asymmetrically to positive and negative return (namely, the leverage effect); (3) return innovations are non-normal distributed.12 Thus, a stochastic volatility model of equity index should take these data features into consideration. In a discrete-time setting, stochastic volatility is always modeled using extensions of autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) model of Engle (1982) and generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH) of Bollerslev (1986). 13 In the presence of time-varying volatility and structure breaks in equity index returns, more recent studies have turned to GARCH models, such as Giacomini and Haerdle (2008) and Christoffersen et al. (2013). Besides, GARCH model has been employed in option pricing (e.g., Duan, 1996; Heston & Nandi, 2000) and in deposit insurance pricing (e.g., Duan & Yu, 1999). These studies find that the GARCH model significantly outperforms its Black-choles counterpart and showed that the GARCH model can exhibits asset risk premium embedded in the underlying assets. GARCH models has been also exploited to forecast VIX and estimate variance risk premium (see, Liu, Guo, and Qiao (2015)).14 In this paper, the estimation of the historical density is based on daily returns to the FTSE 100 index from January 17, 1986 through March 19, 2004. By the Akaike information criterion (AIC) and Schwarz information criterion (SIC), we choose the MA(1)- TGARCH(1,1) specification (Glosten et al., 1993) to fit the historical returns to the FTSE 100 index. In contrast to ordinary GARCH models, the TGARCH model can account for the leverage effect by treating positive and negative shocks differently. Thus, Rosenberg and Engle (2002) and Barone-Adesi, Engle, and Mancini (2008) all fit the TGARCH model to historical returns. We estimate parameters by maximizing the quasi log likelihood function under the assumption of conditional normality.15 The quasi maximum likelihood estimates are still consistent even if the true density is some other than a Gaussian density (Bollerslev & Wooldridge, 1992). To obtain actual density distributions that are compatible with RNDs, the horizons of equity index returns are chosen such that they match the maturity of underlying options and the returns are then smoothed through a kernel density estimator. Thus, after estimating a parametric MA(1)-TGARCH(1,1) model based on historical returns to the FTSE 100 index, we calculate standardized innovation by dividing the innovations by estimated volatility, and then run 10,000 simulations to obtain an actual density distributions by using a Gaussian kernel density estimator with bandwidth equal to 1.8 10, 000 5 , where is the standard deviation of annualized return based on simulated data of index levels and 10,000 denotes the number of replications. The bandwidth is chosen according to Sliverman’s (1986) rule of thumb and is also similar to the one used in Jackwerth (2000). 16 12 For example, there could be jumps in index returns. Jumps could cause the index returns to be mixed-normal distributed. 13 On the other hand, in a continuous-time setting, a stochastic volatility diffusion is often used (Shephard, 1996). 14 For a complete survey of ARCH and GARCH related models, please refer to Bollerslev, Chou, and Kroner (1992) or Bollerslev, Engle, and Nelson (1994). 15 When the assumption of conditional normality is removed, there may affect the simulated shape of a density. It would be left for further tests. 16 Users of nonparametric regressions face a trade-off between smoothness and overfitting. The bandwidth controls the balance between fitting and smoothness. Jackwerth (2000) explained this choice could lead to a slight oversmoothing but remove spurious multimodalities. We have also tried the optimized bandwidth and the results are similar. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 5
WJ.Liao and H.C.Sung 4.Pricing kernel puzzle 4.1.Finding of pricing kemel puzsle Theoretically,the pricing kemel is monotonically decreasing with the level of wealth (Jackwerth,2000,2004).However, level ose to the level ofand exhibited positive and negativerisk aver sion acros levidenceand rep entative-agent theory is refe 么g60宁 sing in wealth and the utility fun ction is convex in w fromem not chan )of1987 earch just searches have r(0)investi ames that the stock index is a good proxy of co sableto geerate the pricn kemel pue ony when two of realistically. ood n y for the regime ing kemel and es hold the sa and positive risk aversion.However,the analytical pricing kemel often do not match the empirical pricing kemels in shape and GARCH model and the e that the Ushaped pricing ke icine kemne d by not nt the empinc the VIX ally.How er.they uld not tablish n add s dis and ly d and varying demand for insur (2004)find that resulting from the index puts 4.2.Possible explanations for pricing kernel puzzle 4.21.Rationality of investors Bondarenko (2014)observes the put prices anomaly,the fact that the prices of the S&P 500 puts have been too high and not Ait-Sahalia and Lo ),Rosenberg and Engle Hil (),and Fenger and Hin (2015)also find local 色a出 u,2011) 6
4. Pricing kernel puzzle 4.1. Finding of pricing kernel puzzle Theoretically, the pricing kernel is monotonically decreasing with the level of wealth (Jackwerth, 2000, 2004). However, Jackwerth (2000) find that the implied pricing kernel function, inferred from the S&P 500 option prices, is locally increasing across wealth after the stock market crash of October 1987. Specifically, Jackwerth observed that the pricing kernel increases for wealth level close to the level of 117 and exhibited positive and negative risk aversion across parts of the wealth level18. This inconsistency of empirical evidence and representative-agent theory is referred as “pricing kernel puzzle” (Jackwerth, 2000, 2004; Rosenberg & Engle, 2002). A locally increasing pricing kernel implies that the investors are partly risk seeking.19 Over the range of increasing pricing kernel, the marginal utility function is increasing in wealth and the utility function is convex in which the investors will pay to play fair gambles in wealth. The pricing kernel puzzle appears around the center of asset return’s distribution and is not affected by mispricing of away-from-the-money options. Moreover, Jackwerth (2000) concludes that market microstructure (e.g. bid-ask spreads, transaction costs, or margin requirements) effects are not likely to explain for this pricing kernel puzzle because the market friction does not change much around the market crash of 1987. In literature, the most of research just studies either the RND or actual probability density individually. Some researches have undertaken to consider both RND and subjective probability density at the same time and deal with the problem of pricing kernel puzzle (Ziegler, 2007; Chabi-Yo et al., 2008; Brown & Jackwerth, 2012; Christoffersen et al., 2013; Song & Xiu, 2016). Ziegler (2007) investigates a complete market with multiple investors and assumes that the stock index is a good proxy of consumption. His results indicate different potential explanations for the pricing kernel puzzle: (i) aggregation of (heterogeneous) preferences, (ii) misestimation of investors’ beliefs, and (iii) heterogeneous beliefs. He shows that aggregation of preferences and misestimation of investors’ beliefs caused by stochastic volatility and jumps are unlikely to be the explanation for the pricing kernel puzzle. When heterogeneous beliefs is allowed, a large share of investors with very pessimistic beliefs is needed to explain the puzzle. A leftskewed RND can only be captured if some investors expect extremely negative returns. However, a setting with three groups of investors is able to generate the pricing kernel puzzle only when two of the groups are unrealistically pessimistic. Ziegler (2007) also suggests that a solution of the pricing kernel puzzle needs to go beyond the standard consumption-based framework with the assumption of complete and frictionless market. Moreover, only consideration of single state variable, such as stock index, may not be a good proxy for the aggregate endowment. Chabi-Yo et al. (2008) extend Garcia, Luger, and Renault’s (2003) option pricing formulas with regime switches to recover analytically the RNDs and actual probability distributions across wealth states, and thus, the pricing kernel functions. They show that the pricing kernel puzzle can be explained by regime shifts in fundamentals (the joint distribution of the pricing kernel and returns), preferences, or beliefs. The pricing kernel functions obtained from calibrated prices in these economies hold the same puzzling features as in Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000) and Jackwerth (2000) and are incompatible with the assumptions of decreasing marginal utility and positive risk aversion. However, the analytical pricing kernel often do not match the empirical pricing kernels in shape and magnitude. A more full-on empirical works might be capable of improve the fit. Christoffersen et al. (2013) also incorporate a variance risk premium in addition to equity premium into the Heston and Nandi (2000) GARCH model, and the pricing kernel is a function of return and volatility. They showe that the U-shaped pricing kernel emerges. However, the quadratic functional form of pricing kernel assumed by the GARCH model at times does not fit the empirical tilde-shaped kernel in the empirical section of their paper. Song and Xiu (2016) add information about the VIX level in estimating pricing kernel for the S&P 500 and find U-shaped pricing kernel unconditionally. However, they could not establish it conditionally on high or low VIX levels. In addition, as discussed in Rosenberg and Engle (2002) and Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000), the pricing kernel puzzle indicates an asymmetrically decreasing pricing kernels on either side of the wealth. Rosenberg and Engle (2002) infer that this could reflect timevarying demand for insurance against a significant market decline. Furthermore, Bollen and Whaley (2004) find that excess buying pressure on out-of-the money puts, formed from a demand for portfolio insurance, is negatively related to the slope of volatility smile. Bollen and Whaley (2004) also find that changes in volatility of the S&P 500 index are strongly affected by the buying pressure resulting from the index puts. 4.2. Possible explanations for pricing kernel puzzle 4.2.1. Rationality of investors Bondarenko (2014) observes the put prices anomaly, the fact that the prices of the S&P 500 puts have been too high and not 17Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000), Rosenberg and Engle, 2002, Hill (2013), and Fengler and Hin (2015) also find local increasing pricing kernel on the S&P 500. A number of following studies on other indexes also find similar results, such as Giacomini and Haerdle (2008) and Grith, Haerdle, and Park (2013) on DAX, and Haerdle, Grith, and Mihoci (2014) on international cross sections of 20 stock indices. 18 The use of price limits, designed to serve as a price stabilization mechanism to assure the proper operation of futures markets, has received a lot of attentions since the 1987 crash. Studies show that the effectiveness of price limits depends on the traders’ degree of risk aversion (Chou, Lin, & Yu, 2005; Lin & Chou, 2011). 19 Typically, investors are risk averse and the pricing kernel is monotonically decreasing across wealth. For an investor, a promise of one dollar payoff received in a state of the world when she is already wealthy is worthless to her than in a state of the world when she is poor. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 6
WJ.Liao and H.-C Sung North Americen Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020)10082 valued put options are summarized in ondarnk(2014 ary pro 上心时 ash-like re s for puts,because rofhistorical negative the stock market crash of October 1987). ices.Bondarenko (2003a)used an eauilibrium 100 ind ine k n 5,we use a 4.2.2.Brown and Jackwerth(2012)model afeheoflowoiaiiy,tisasociatedwMithmoderatelevesofweath.supp ose thatfollows asimple mean reverting proces row and A储一c0设e元 J(Wi.X.)=maxE.fexp(-p)(C:)-/(1-)dr a1) dw.=(Wa.(u-n)+Wir-C)dt aWg(X,)dz dX:=-X:dt aX)dZ. (12) Changes in the welth of a representative agent as follows J(Wi.X.t)=e-g(X)(W)-/(1-y). The solutions for consumption and the proportion of the risky asset are C.=g(X(W). a3) If we further assume that the riskless asset is in zero net supply,so that then Eq.(1)indicates that Moreover,the pricing kemel can be derived from the ratio of marginal utilities: This pricing kemel dependson the ratio f We can specify the function form follows g(X)=d+ and Jackwerth (2012) 7
compatible with the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and Rubinstein (1976). Since the puts are over-priced, investors that just trade on at-the-money and out-of-the-money puts would earn extraordinary profits. Three possible explanations about the overvalued put options are summarized in Bondarenko (2014): 1. Risk premium: Investors abominate crash-like returns of S&P 500 and are willing to pay considerable premiums for puts, because this provides an explicit insurance against market declines (Rosenberg & Engle, 2002; Bollen & Whaley, 2004). 2. The peso problem: An event occurs infrequently is out of the scope of rational expectations. 3. Biased beliefs: Investors overstate the true probability of extreme declines because of the terror of historical negative returns (e.g. the stock market crash of October 1987). To investigate the anomaly in put prices, Bondarenko (2003a) used an equilibrium model to determine the rationality of put returns and set up a new rationality restriction in the equilibrium model. However, the pricing kernel puzzle still can not resolved. In this paper, we also find evidence of pricing kernel puzzle in the data of FTSE 100 index option prices. In Section 5, we use a reasonable set of parameters to simulate the model of Brown and Jackwerth (2012) to resolve the problem of pricing kernel puzzle. 4.2.2. Brown and Jackwerth (2012) model To resolve the pricing kernel puzzle, Brown and Jackwerth (2012) add more than one state variable to the utility function. In a representative agent model with a power utility function and small risk aversion coefficient, Brown and Jackwerth (2012) use a second state variable, XT, in addition to wealth ( WT), to specify the utility function. Brown and Jackwerth (2012) recognize the characteristic of volatility smile from the data of option prices and used volatility as the second state variable. Suppose there are two states: high-volatility state and low-volatility state. In the state of high volatility, it corresponds to very high and low levels of wealth; in the state of low volatility, it is associated with moderate levels of wealth. Suppose that Xt follows a simple mean reverting process. As argued in Merton (1969) and Brown and Jackwerth (2012), in the economy of one representative agent, the investor chooses the rate of consumption C W X t ( , , ) t t , the proportion of wealth in the risky asset, ( , , ) W X t t t , and the proportion in the risk-free asset, (1 ) , to maximize the expected utility of lifetime consumption as follows: J W X t E ( , , ) max exp( )( ) /(1 ) t t C d C t t , 1 (11) = + + = + dW W µ r W r C dt W X dZ dX X dt X dZ ( ( ) ) ( ) , ( ) , t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t (12) where is the discount factor, is the risk aversion coefficient, Wt is the first state variable which represents the agent’s wealth at date t X, t is the other state variable, Ct is the consumption, rt is the risk-free rate, µ and are constant, ( ) Xt 2 is the variance of Xt and is a function of the second state variable Xt, and Z is a standard Brownian motion appears in both diffusion processes. Changes in the second state variable Xt are perfectly correlated with changes in wealth Wt . As shown in Brown and Jackwerth (2012), if we specify the utility of wealth of a representative agent as follows, J W X t e g X W ( , , ) ( )( ) /(1 ). t = t t t 1 The solutions for consumption and the proportion of the risky asset are C g X W = ( ) ( ), t t t 1/ (13) = + µ r g X g X ( ) ( ) ( ). t t t t 2 (14) If we further assume that the riskless asset is in zero net supply, so that t = 1 , then Eq. (14) indicates that r µ = X + g X g X ( ) X ( ) ( ) ( ) . t t t t t 2 2 Moreover, the pricing kernel can be derived from the ratio of marginal utilities: = = = J J e g X g X W W e g X g X r ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) . t T W W T t T t T t T t T t , t T ( ) ( ) , , T t This pricing kernel depends on the ratio of g X g X ( ) ( ) T t . We can specify the function form of g (·) as follows: = + + + g X d e ( ) . a bX cX2 As we choose some possible parameters of d a b , , , and c, we can obtain the pricing kernel function. In Brown and Jackwerth (2012), for the data of S&P 500 index, the parameters are set as follows: W X 0 0 = = = = = = = = 1, 0, 0.5, 0.1, 8, 0, 500 d a b c . The standard deviation of Xt is set as ( ) 0.06 0.2 Xt = + Xt 2 . Based on 10,000 simulations, the simulated pricing kernel presents to be locally increasing in wealth around a wealth level of 1. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 7
WJ.Liao and H.C.Sung 5.Empirical results based on the FTSE 100 index option prices 5.1.The data The data of futures and options prices data used in this paper are obtained from the London Intemational Financial Futures and res on FTSE 1 ave the same expiry he PS1inde can be valed bynthefucorthe1indeing the RND each day.T.the third Friday of every month on-overlapping data specifically in March.June.September and ated fai tures prices are the future value of the spot rice minus the present =(T-》(S-5,). 经e eadoptncareobtaned ted in Ait.Sahalia and Lo (2000):replacing all P(SK,out-of-the-money and liquid.By doing this way,all the information in the content of liquid put prices can be ata at first.We include op with need to age lo ”bo ondition: onditions ity).We also exclude s nrices that are decre于 ne)in the strike es,and that violate the maximum vertical spread 5.2.Comparing RNDs and actual probabilities density ive the RNDs. 2 Table 2 reports the summary means of RNDs a the dis orical density ity.The negative skew to be nega be posi reover,the the money puts to put a floor on the maximum losses they can sustain. 20 Liu shackleto 线itis
5. Empirical results based on the FTSE 100 index option prices 5.1. The data The data of futures and options prices data used in this paper are obtained from the London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange (LIFFE). Both futures and options are written on the FTSE 100 index. The data covers the 27 months from January 2002 through March 2004. We use daily tick data for bid quotes and ask quotes and actual trades in this study. The average bid and ask prices are used to avoid bid-ask bounce effect. We adopt the London Eurocurrency rate as the risk-free interest rate.20 The data of Eurocurrency is obtained from DataStream. In any time, five option contracts are traded with expiration in current and nearby three months, and one following expiration month in March, June, September, and December. Data of every month from January 2002 through March 2004 are used to estimate RNDs and actual probability densities. RNDs are retrieved from FTSE 100 index option prices, and actual probability densities are obtained from index returns. The risk aversion functions for a representative investor with 1-month investment horizon are inverted from the ratio of actual probability density and RND. In the LIFFE, the options on FTSE 100 index are European options. Options and futures on FTSE 100 index have the same expiry month and expiration time, which is 10:30 a.m. (London time) on the third Friday of the expiry month. Hence, European options on the FTSE 100 index can be valued by assuming they are written on the futures contracts the on FTSE 100 index. In reverting the RND from option prices, we do not need spot prices of the FTSE 100 index. Our data cover 27 sets of cross-section data, therefore we obtain 27 RNDs for each expiry day, Ti, the third Friday of every month. For each Ti, we choose ti to be exactly 31 days before Ti. That is, we fix the option lives at 31 days and obtain 27 non-overlapping data sets. The non-overlapping feature allows us to avoid some estimation and inference biases. However, futures contracts are traded with only one expiration date every quarter, specifically in March, June, September and December. We need to find synthetic futures prices for the other months. Calculated fair futures prices are the future value of the spot price minus the present value of dividends during the life of the futures contract. That is, F e S = ( ), t r T t t t ( ( )) where St is the spot price, r is risk-free rate, t denotes the present value of dividend payments between t and T. The data of dividends of the 100 component stocks in the FTSE 100 index are obtained from DataStream. To avoid the illiquidity problem, we adopt the data selection principle suggested in Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000): replacing all illiquid options, that is, in-the-money options, with the price implied by the put-call parity at the corresponding strike prices. We replace the price of each in-the-money call option by P S K T t r ( , , , , ) ( ) t t + e F K r T t t ( ) , where the put with a price of P S K T t r ( , , , , ) t t is out-of-the-money and liquid. By doing this way, all the information in the content of liquid put prices can be retrieved from call prices. Since the FTSE 100 options data may contain mispriced prices, we should filter the original data at first. We include options with moneyness ( / ) K Ft between 0.82 and 1.16. Options prices also need to satisfy the no-arbitrage lower bound condition: P Max e K F t [0, ] r T t t ( ) or C Max F e K t [0, t )] r T t ( ) . On the other hand, we eliminate the call (put) options data that violates noarbitrage conditions (put-call parity). We also exclude options prices that are decreasing (increasing) in the strike prices, and that violate the maximum vertical spread premium condition. In each cross-section sample, we have at least fifteen options (both calls and puts) satisfying selection criteria. Table 1 reports the summary of option data used in this study. It provided information about the moneyness of the option prices. 5.2. Comparing RNDs and actual probabilities density In this paper, we apply two nonparametric methods, including IV and PCA methods, to derive the RNDs. Our data covers 27 representative monthly expiration day’s options price, hence we obtain 27 estimated RNDs from each nonparametric method. Fig. 1 shows the averages of RNDs from IV and PCA methods, and the actual probability density, across K F/ t. Table 2 reports the summary statistics of all densities. The means of RNDs are approximately 1. The average standard deviation of historical density is lower than that of two RNDs from IV and PCA methods. However, the dispersion of standard deviation (0.046–0.051) is quite stable for actual historical density. We find both RNDs are negatively skewed, with the average skewness between −0.67 and −0.62, that is far from the average level of −0.010 for the historical density. The negative skewness in the option-based densities is consistent with the belief that the subsequent monthly returns are likely to be negative than to be positive. Moreover, the RNDs is likely to be leptokurtic than that of historical density. It also shows that the historical density appears to be (log) normally distributed, whereas the RNDs are left skewed and leptokurtic. That is, they have fat left-tails and higher peaks than a normal distribution. This is consistent with the underlying volatility smile depicted in Fig. 2 in which the left tail of the plot is substantially above the right. As mentioned in Rubinstein (1994), the downward-sloping volatility smile could be related to stock market crashes where investors insure themselves by buying out-ofthe money puts to put a floor on the maximum losses they can sustain. 20 Liu, Shackleton, Taylor, and Xu (2007) argue that, because the Eurocurrency rate is a market rate accessible to AAA corporate borrowers, it is a better consideration for risk-free rate in the London stock market. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 8
WJ.Liao and H.-C Sun North Americen Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020)10082 Table 1 ry for Number of epr h date.we extr f options (in oth puts and one month unti trage conditions are eli ated,and put- There are 26 estimation dates in the sample berofa0sstctongl s pe 002w 0.0000 Fig.1.Risk Neutral Densities tpnehot o ≡ 删 串月号 溢 洲 猫
Table 1 Summary for cross-session samples of FTSE 100 index options. Moneyness Number of Average Average Average (K F/ t) observationa implied volatility call price put price 0.82 to 0.87 52 0.3153 692.3391 14.404 0.87 to 0.91 73 0.2661 496.5859 21.0393 0.91 to 0.95 84 0.2237 337.3548 32.3331 0.95 to 0.99 88 0.1970 197.066 61.9130 0.99 to 1.03 93 0.1748 86.9640 128.7658 1.03 to 1.07 78 0.1737 34.4632 244.0038 1.07 to 1.11 40 0.2046 19.3014 374.1835 1.11 to 1.16 23 0.2359 9.3658 536.1607 Notes: The data is obtained from the London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange (LIFFE) during the period fron January 2002 through March 2004. Ft is the price of futures on the FTSE 100 index. and K is the exercise price of the FTSE 100 index options. For every representative monthly observed date, we extract a cross section of options (including both puts and calls) with approximately one month until expiration (each third Friday of the expiry month). We consider options with moneyness between 0.82 and 1.16. Option quotes violating general noarbitrage conditions are eliminated, and put-call parity is used. There are 26 estimation dates in the sample, and the number of cross sectional observations per estimation date varies from 15 to 27. Fig. 1. Risk Neutral Densities. Table 2 Moments for risk neutral densities (RNDs) and real-world densities. RND RND Real-world (PCA method) (IV method) Density Mean Minimum 0.9818 1.0008 0.999 Maximum 1.0038 1.0117 1.0003 Average 0.9985 1.0037 1.00029 Std. dev. Minimum 0.0320 0.0370 0.0458 Maximum 0.1020 0.0906 0.0513 Average 0.0610 0.0625 0.0490 Skewness Minimum −1.708 −1.134 −0.0156 Maximum 0.299 −0.151 −0.0058 Average −0.6505 −0.6347 −0.0103 Kurtosis Minimum 2.0603 2.2846 2.9543 Maximum 7.7324 5.1810 2.9738 Average 4.4915 3.4217 2.9646 W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 9
WJ.Liao and H.C.Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54(2020)100826 02 0.15 0840.880910.950.991.031071.111.15 KF 15 6 一W"O 05 0.91 0.% 1.D2 1明 Fig.3.Empirical pricing Kernels 5.3.Empirical pricing kemnels and risk aversior e we invert impli d RNDs and actual probability der ywe can der TGARCH ori al returns geometric mean o ch set of kerels isused uce noise cre the data and the dif sets.Th we s K/F ind This patter indicates the repr nt is ses for m the starting le se of Al d R pmanh typ rth(2012) erved a very t that the and Jackwerth(01),the locally increasing pricing kemel indi ates that the utility functionsof t the inveto oul pay toobtan frbened of mpocketing the ors are I hle fo Further RRA bas RND (hereafter,RND),it is dec sing in K/F when K/and inc ing as K/F>102.Therefore the constant relative ris ND O Iv m ustudies that
5.3. Empirical pricing kernels and risk aversion Once we invert implied RNDs and actual probability density, we can derive empirical pricing kernel. We use two nonparametric methods, including the IV surface interpolation method and PCA method, to derive RNDs from option prices. The actual probability density is simulated based on an asymmetric TGARCH model applied to historical returns. The geometric mean of each set of kernels is used to reduce noise created by the data and the different information sets. Then, we plot the geometric means of the two sets of empirical pricing kernels against the moneyness variable K F/ in Fig. 3. It shows that the estimated pricing kernel is downward sloping as moneyness K F/ increases. This pattern indicates the representative agent is risk averse. However, it increases for moneyness level close to the starting level of 0.97 at times. These results are similar to those of AitSahalia and Lo (2000), Rosenberg and Engle (2002), and Brown and Jackwerth (2012). In Ait-Sahalia and Lo (2000) and Rosenberg and Engle (2002), both pricing kernels have a region of increasing marginal utility. By using S&P 500 index data from April 1986 to December 1995, Brown and Jackwerth (2012) observed a very clear hump-shaped marginal utility function from approximate moneyness 0.97 to 1.03. This challenges economic theory and points out that the representative agent is somehow risk seeking in some region. As suggested by Brown and Jackwerth (2012), the locally increasing pricing kernel indicates that the utility functions of investors are locally convex. In that case, the investors would pay to obtain fair gamble instead of simply pocketing the expected value of the gamble for sure. Furthermore, we can derive the implied relative risk aversion (RRA) function, Ar by using Eq. (8). Fig. 4 depicts Ar against the moneyness, K F/ . We find that RRA implied from FTSE 100 index option, Ar , is downward sloping when K F/ 0.98 , and upward sloping when K F/ is on the right of 0.98 based on the RND derived from PCA method. Regarding RRA based on the IV-method RND (hereafter, RND VI ), it is decreasing in K F/ when K F/ 1.02 and increasing as K F/ 1.02 > . Therefore, the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) is not a very precise description for the London stock market. The average RRA from the RND of IV method is 11.93, and 8.68 from the RND of PCA method. Table 3 presents a comparison of the range of average Ar estimates from pervious studies that Fig. 2. Implied Volatility Smile. Fig. 3. Empirical pricing Kernels. W.J. Liao and H.-C. Sung North American Journal of Economics and Finance 54 (2020) 100826 10